July 19: New York State Department of Labor Reports a Gain of 15,500 Jobs in June

The New York State Department of Labor reported a gain of 15,500 jobs statewide in June.  Employment in the state is up 1.1% over a year ago, less than the nationwide gain of 1.6%.  The BLS reported a loss of 6,000 jobs in New York City in June, though employment is up 1.4% over a year ago.      

July 19: New York State Department of Labor Reports a Gain of 15,500 Jobs in June2018-07-27T19:03:14+00:00

A Primer on Real Versus Nominal

Harvey Gram
July 22, 2018

The word “nominal” suggests insignificance. A “nominal tip” is small. “Nominally in charge” means “in name only” i.e. not really in charge. A money-valued variable such as GDP in dollars, pesos, Euros, etc. is described as nominal for much the same reason. Its change may not be “real”. The same thing applies to rates of return. A nominal interest rate of 25% per annum on a government bond with a principal value of $10,000 sounds great: $2,500 per year before taxes. If prices are rising at 25% per annum, however, the real return is zero because the interest payment just makes up for the loss of purchasing power of the principal. In fact, the return is negative after taxes, because nominal income, not real income, is subject to taxation.

Nominal values are, in principle, easy to calculate. In the case of nominal GDP, simply record the dollar value of every final good or service produced over the course of a year—a monumental task, to be sure, but not one requiring any conceptual thought other than to avoid double counting. Count the value of the bread sold, but not the flour used to bake it or the grain that is ground up to make the flour, a likewise for all other goods and services.

Nominal U.S. GDP is about $20 trillion. It passed the $100 billion mark in 1940, indicating a 200-fold increase—about 6.9% compounded annually. How much of this was a result of rising prices and how much was a real increase in the quantities of goods and services produced each year?

The Index Number Problem

Government statisticians calculate a wide range of price indices. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) publishes the GDP deflator and the Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE) price index, used by the Federal Reserve to estimate inflation. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) publishes the headline Consumer Price Index for all Urban Consumers (CPI-U) and the Consumer Price Index for Urban Wage Earners and Clerical Workers (CPI-W), used to adjust Social Security Benefits each year (2.0% higher for 2018).

Two basic problems arise in constructing any index number for prices (or quantities). (1) What is the appropriate average of the underlying price (quantity) changes? (2) What should be done to adjust for the fact that a good or service with the same name changes in quality over time while some are essentially new goods and services?

First Problem: Expenditure shares as weights in an average of prices

The Consumer Price Index for Urban dwellers (CPI-U) is a weighted average of eight sub-indexes aggregating 211 categories of goods and services for which the data are collected across 38 geographic areas.

  Category Expenditure Share
1 Food and Beverages .15
2 Housing .42
3 Apparel .03
4 Transportation .15
5 Medical Care .08
6 Recreation .06
7 Education and Communication .07
8 Other Goods and Services .04

 

The weights on sub-indexes, all the way down to individual ratios of new to old prices, vary because of inflation when expenditure shifts away from goods and services that have increased in price the most towards relatively cheaper ones.

A price index using expenditure share weights that precede price changes is a Laspeyres price index (Ernst Laspeyres, 1834-1913). One that uses weights that follow price changes is a Paasche price index (Hermann Paasche, 1851-1925). The CPI-U is close to a Laspeyres price index (the weights are a little older than the initial prices) and, for that reason, is said to overestimate inflation. It fails to allow fully for the expenditure-share reaction to inflation. This does not mean that a Paasche price index would be any better. It would underestimate inflation because it assumes that the reaction to inflation has occurred before the prices rise.

The BEA compromise is the square root of the product of what are essentially Laspeyres and Paasche price indices. The resulting PCE price index is a Fisher index (Irving Fisher, 1867-1947). It has the advantage that the product of Fisher price and quantity indices yields exactly the factor by which nominal GDP has increased.

The BLS solution is more complex—namely, the product of the ratios of new to old prices for various categories of goods and services, each raised to a power equal to the average of expenditure shares for the current month and the same month a year earlier. The result is a Törnqvist price index (Leo Törnqvist, 1911-1983), called a “chain” index because, as time passes, the end share of one month is the beginning share for the next month.

Second Problem: What’s in a name?

Goods like automobiles can be viewed as “bundles” of various qualities: “safety, reliability, performance, durability, fuel economy, carrying capacity, maneuverability, comfort, and convenience” (BLS Handbook of Methods, chapter 17, page 25). If all qualities were for sale in every time period, the market price of each quality difference could be ascertained. Because this is not the case, various compromises and guesswork must go into deciding whether an increase in price should be counted as inflation or as a real improvement.

In the extreme, an entirely new good or service has no previous price while goods no longer produced have no current price. Music streaming services are entirely new. It would be absurd to stick to the price of vinyl recordings in an effort to measure the change in the price of listening to music. The price of a smartphone compared to a dial telephone raises the same issue. Rapid technological change makes this second aspect of the index number problem at least as important as the first.

A final note

Inflation factors (1 plus the inflation rate) and growth factors (1 plus the rate of growth of the corresponding quantities) ought to “add up”. An inflation factor times a growth factor for the same set of goods and services should equal the corresponding nominal factor (1 plus the rate of change of the nominal value). Now, suppose you have the nominal factor and you have gone to the trouble of estimating the inflation factor. Then, to save time, you just divide the nominal factor by the inflation factor to obtain the real growth factor, and hence the real growth rate. It should be obvious that if you underestimate inflation, you will automatically overestimate real growth. When there is political gain in exaggerating growth, there is political gain in under-estimating inflation. A suspiciously high reported growth rate might just be a consequence of underestimating inflation.

As for the U.S., Tables 1.1.3 and 1.1.9 from the NIPA show that the average annual 6.9% rate of change in nominal GDP since 1940 is accounted for by a virtually equal split between real growth and inflation, each at about 3.4% per year. (The product of the corresponding factors, each equal to 1.034, is 1.069, as expected.) Of course, there was variation around these means. Ignoring the extraordinary swing in the growth rate during and after the Second World War (from 18.9% in 1942 to negative 11.6% in 1946), one still observes a wide range of values from 1960 to the present, ranging from in 7.3% in 1984 to negative 2.8% in 2009. On the inflation side, the extremes of the 1940s again stand out: almost 13% in 1946 followed by a slightly negative number three years later. More recently, 1981 stands out for its high inflation rate of 9.3% while 2009 again enters the record books with inflation at less than 1%. The recent Great Recession was characterized by falling real output and virtually no inflation.

A Primer on Real Versus Nominal2018-07-22T19:03:14+00:00

June 14: The New York State Department of Labor Reported a Gain of 12,300 Jobs Statewide in May

The New York State Department of Labor reported a gain of 12,300 jobs statewide in May. Employment in the state is up 1.1% over a year ago, less than the nationwide gain of 1.6%.  The BLS reported a gain of 11,300 jobs in New York City in May.  These gains reversed some weakness in city employment growth in March and April and raised year-over-year job growth to 1.8%. 

June 14: The New York State Department of Labor Reported a Gain of 12,300 Jobs Statewide in May2018-06-20T03:55:44+00:00

A Primer on Stocks and Flows (Part 2)

Harvey Gram
June 06, 2018

1. Be Wary of the Words—and the Rhetoric

“Debts” and “deficits” seem to have negative connotations. Still, every debt/liability for one party is a credit/asset for some counter-party who willingly holds the corresponding security; and every deficit has its matching surplus somewhere in a complete and consistent set of accounts. The argument is nevertheless heard that government debt, in particular, is always a burden—a burden on “our grandchildren”, innocent victims of the government’s current profligacy and corresponding deficits that can only be financed by selling more debt. A perfectly sensible question often gets lost in the rhetoric. Is the future cost of servicing government debt larger or smaller than the future benefit associated with debt-financed expenditures? Is it always better to raise taxes to cover the expenditure in question, thereby avoiding the deficits that fuel the rise in debt? Whether or not a particular expenditure is justified should be argued separately from the way in which it is to be financed.

Individuals face such questions all the time. How does the (flow) cost of servicing a mortgage stand up against the expected (flow) benefit of living in a house (a stock) and thereby saving on rent (a flow)? How does the (flow) cost of servicing a student loan stand up against the expected higher (flow) of earnings from having a college degree (a stock)? Would anyone seriously argue that households would be better off without the choice of entering into such debt contracts? That would require saving up enough to buy a house outright before living in it, or paying for an education before benefiting financially from a better paying job? Of course, renting can make more sense than owning for some households (though tax breaks often tell in favor in owning); and success in life comes to some who have only a high school education. Still, these are not arguments for making debt contracts illegal. If borrowers do not understand the terms of debt contracts, greater transparency on the part of the lenders is called for—and may have to be enforced by government regulations.

Certain types of government spending on, say, infrastructure projects benefit the same people who will be taxed to pay interest on the debt issued to pay for the project, just as the owner of a house who makes monthly mortgage payments benefits from the shelter it provides. Such linking of costs and benefits actually occurs when a government dedicates user fees (e.g. tolls) to service the debt issued to pay for new infrastructure (e.g. a bridge or highway) and to maintain it. This is not always easy to do, but any informed discussion of the burden of the debt ought to be concerned with such matters. In any case, there is no more sense to a blanket condemnation of government debt, especially when the government can borrow long-term at relatively low interest rates, than there is to a blanket condemnation of corporate and personal debt.

Deficit “hawks” respond to such arguments with a seemingly straightforward question: “But, what about the day when the debt comes due?” The answer is that it comes due every day. New bonds routinely replace maturing debt. The “hawks” retort: “And, what if the interest rate on replacement debt is higher? Sounds like a Ponzi scheme to me!” Well, sometimes interest rates on new debt are lower, causing total debt service actually to fall, but that is not an answer. There is a germ of truth in the “hawks” fear-mongering, but it has nothing to do with some final day of reckoning. After all, the holders of government debt are quite happy with their assets, and, if the bonds in their portfolios mature, new ones can be purchased to maintain the desired flow of interest income. So, what is that germ of truth in the argument of the deficit “hawks” who see in every increase of outstanding government debt a harbinger of immanent economic collapse?

The ratio of government debt to gross domestic product is a legitimate concern. Its numerical value can be confusing, however, because GDP is an annual flow. Measure GDP on a six-month basis and the debt to GDP ratio immediately doubles; measure it on a decennial basis and the same ratio suddenly falls to one-tenth its “annual” value. A ratio that does not suffer from this defect is debt-service (interest) divided by GDP. Both are flows over the same period whatever that may be.

The Federal Debt/GDP ratio peaked at 119% in 1946 following World War II during which purchases of debt by the public was advertised as a patriotic duty. The campaign was hugely successful, thereby funding the war effort without a huge tax increase while endowing the public with an income earning asset. The Federal Debt/GDP ratio then fell steadily to about 31% in 1981, primarily because of rising GDP (although there were six surplus years). More recently, the debt/GDP ratio rose sharply in the years following the recent financial crisis and is now about 104% of GDP. Canada’s ratio is somewhat lower; Japan’s is well over twice the US ratio.

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Series GFDGDPA188S

Even a sharp rise in the Federal debt/GDP ratio need not be accompanied by a similar trend in the ratio of Federal interest payments to GDP. At 2.6% of GDP, the present ratio is about three times its minimum 1944 value, but well under its 1991 value of almost 5%. A rising debt/GDP ratio and a simultaneously falling debt-service/GDP ratio simply reflects historically low interest rates on recently issued government debt.

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, NIPA Table 3.2, Line 32

A final caution is in order concerning the word “deficit”. Whenever the U.S. Current Account is in deficit, it is necessarily the case that the U.S. Financial Account Balance is in surplus. Our trade surplus in services and our surplus on income account are more than offset by our trade deficit in goods and our excess of taxes and transfers paid over what we receive. There is only one way to finance the resulting Current Account, and that is to sell more claims on future US income than we buy on future foreign income. These are capital account transactions and selling more than we buy is the definition of a surplus. Anyone who prefers the word “surplus” can simply talk about the Financial Account rather than the Current Account, “celebrating” the fact that the U.S. is a “great place” to invest. Don’t be fooled. The Current Account deficit is the same thing (with sign reversed) as the Financial Account surplus! Any policy that changes one will automatically change the other.

2. Conceptual Issues

Because stocks and flows involve time, the question arises: What happens to the distinction when the length of time over which the flows are measured is shortened or lengthened? If we imagine stopping time so that the rivers stop flowing and wind stops blowing, everything becomes a stock because we are stuck in an instant of time. If we lengthen the period of time sufficiently to allow a stock of, say, automobiles, to completely wear out and be replaced with different ones, then the stock has “turned over” and become a flow. The less durable a good, the shorter the time over which a stock becomes a flow. Hence, in the market for fresh milk or fish, it makes analytical sense to treat supply and demand as flows, even though at a moment in time the amounts of fresh milk and fish are stocks. In the market for residential housing, on the other hand, the main influence on price will be the existing stock of previously built houses—the dog that wags the tail in the market for the flow of newly constructed houses.

It always makes sense to ask if a variable is a stock or a flow because it forces one to think about units of measurement. Is labor a stock or a flow? When we see a symbol for labor as an argument in a firm’s production function, it is surely a flow, “work per unit of time” for that is what matters to a process of production yielding a flow of output. At the same time, a worker with particular skills and experience is just as surely an asset, and therefore a stock. Employers, who cannot legally buy and sell their stock of workers—something they can do with their stocks of plant and equipment—often go to considerable trouble to control the workers they do not own. Non-disclosure clauses in employment contracts and non-portable pensions are examples. When economists conceptualize laborers as a stock, they are not pretending that workers are slaves, but simply trying to model the fact that investments by firms in worker training are sometimes curtailed because the “improved” labor-assets can just walk out the door at any time. As for maximizing the flow of work that the stock of labor provides, this involves complex questions of organization and corporate structure, the province of management science.

Knowledge, in general, like the skills and accumulated experience of workers, is a stock. The flows that create knowledge are the activities of teaching and learning, which take time. Knowledge, however, has a vital and distinguishing property. Unlike a stock of machines, which, when used, generally depreciates as a result of wear and tear, knowledge can increase simply by being used and will surely disappear from not being used. Computer-aided storage of knowledge and its retrieval for use brings up the whole question of the relationship between the existing stock of knowledge and the creative process, which is an intrinsic aspect of the ongoing flow activity of production.

Using the conceptual distinction between stocks and flows when considering economic problems, from healthcare to environmental conservation to the development of new technologies, and much else, will always bring clarity to your thinking.

A Primer on Stocks and Flows (Part 2)2018-07-04T19:37:45+00:00

A Primer on Stocks and Flows (Part 1)

Harvey Gram
May 18, 2018

The distinction between stocks and flows is essential to economic reasoning. In many cases, it is just common sense. If I tell you that my income is $1000, am I a prince or a pauper? Is it $1000 per hour or $1000 per year? Income is a flow, which must have a time dimension in order to be meaningful. In contrast, if I tell you that my wealth is $1,000,000, you should not be puzzled because wealth is a stock, measured at a point in time. Indeed, if I were to say that my wealth is $1,000,000 per week, you should be puzzled. Is it $1,000,000 at the end of each week; or, on average, $1,000,000 at noon on each day of the week? To keep your stocks and flows in line, always ask of an economic variable: What are its units of measurement and do these units have a time dimension?

A simple case: transporting oil

Imagine closing the valves at each end of an oil pipeline. The oil trapped inside is a stock, measured at a “point in time”. The oil inside all the tankers now at sea is also a stock. The flow of oil through a pipeline occurs over a period of time and depends on the pressure applied to the liquid. In the case of tankers at sea, the delivered flow depends on the number and speed of the ships heading towards some destination. Stocks and flows are intrinsic to transportation problems: goods-in-transit are the stocks; deliveries are the flows over periods of time. Part of the cost of transport is the interest (or other income) that could have been earned on the money, metaphorically “tied up” in the stock—a stock that must be maintained in order for any flow to occur.

Accountants live off the distinction: Income Statements and Balance Sheets

An individual’s Balance Sheet records the values of assets and liabilities. These are stocks, measured at a point in time. The word is used generically, while shares (common and preferred) refer to securities listed on the Stock Exchange. Assets minus liabilities is a residual liability, called net worth, which ensures equality of both sides of the Balance Sheet, a requirement of double entry bookkeeping. Negative net worth simply means that liabilities exceed assets and may signal impending bankruptcy.

On the Income Statement, we find flows of income and expenditure, measured over a period of time, often a year. Income minus expenditure is treated as a residual expenditure, called saving, to ensure equality of both sides of the Income Statement. Positive saving implies a current account surplus. When expenditure exceeds income, saving is negative and the current account is in deficit. A nation’s Current Account Balance just extends this notion of surpluses and deficits for an individual to cover an entire country.

The Balance Sheet and the Income Statement interact. If the flow of income exceeds the flow of expenditure (positive residual saving, or a surplus), then at the end of the period over which the flows are measured, either assets are higher, or liabilities are lower (or both). There is a reverse connection as well. To the extent that assets include common and preferred shares, bonds, and real estate, income will necessarily include corresponding dividends, interest, and rent. Likewise, with liabilities: interest on a loan, for example, counts as an expenditure.

Capital gains and losses complicate the picture. Between two dates, the value of each particular asset or liability can change independently of the income statement. Thus, an individual can have a higher stock of wealth at the end of a period during which expenditure exceeds income (negative residual saving), just so long as capital gains exceed capital losses by a sufficient amount to more than offset the individual’s current account deficit.

The US National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) and Net International Investment Position (NIIP)

A perennial topic in the financial news concerns an entire nation’s Income Statement, taking account of all households, firms, and governments (federal, state, and local). This accounting of flows appears in the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). US expenditure on goods and services exceeded US income in almost every year since 1982. (In 1991, the US received a large transfer from Japan during the first Gulf War prompted by Iraq’s invasion of Kuwait, which had threatened oil shipments.) The largest negative value, -$804.2 billion, occurred in 2006. Negative lending to the rest of the world is the same thing as borrowing from foreign individuals, firms, and governments who, in the process, acquire claims on future US income.

Source: National Income and Product Account, Table 5.1, line 35

Just as an individual cannot spend at a rate that exceeds income without drawing down initial assets or incurring new liabilities, so the US has been either selling its accumulated claims on foreigners or selling new claims on itself to foreigners in recent decades. This occurs on a net basis. US claims on foreigners have actually being going up in every year since 1976, when official data on the US Net International Investment Position (NIIP) was first published. However, foreign claims on the US have being increasing at a faster pace. Such foreign claims take the form of ownership of US money, shares, bonds, land, factories, and buildings. When you read that foreigners own many of the apartments in the most expensive residential areas of New York City, think of this fact as the flip side of US current account deficit in action.

The US NIIP with respect to the rest of the world turned negative in 1989 and has remained so ever since. The most recent entry for 2017 is -$7.845 trillion, an excess of liabilities over assets. This is a stock concept determined by the sum of all past deficits and surpluses from the NIPA flow accounts. Does negative net worth imply impending bankruptcy? Not if our future income (a flow) is sufficient to keep on paying the incomes (e.g. interest and dividends) that foreigners expect to receive on what, for them, are assets.

Source: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, International Data, Table 1.1., line 1

For various reasons, there is not always a tight link between the negative annual US net flow rate of saving and the contemporaneous change in the US NIIP. One problem is the difficulty of accurately measuring international trade in services, not to mention private transfers (which may involve illegal transactions). Another is the problem of accounting for capital gains and losses. The US enjoys the ability to borrow in its own currency, i.e. most claims on the US are denominated in US dollars and so, from the US point of view, are unaffected by changes in exchange rates. However, many US claims on foreigners are denominated in foreign currencies, which, in some years, appreciate; thereby increasing the US dollar value of US owned foreign currency denominated claims. Appreciation of the US dollar has the opposite effect. Part of the fluctuation in the US NIIP occurs because of such changes in exchange rates.

Between the individual and the nation as a whole, there are many sub-aggregates. The flow accounts for the consolidated (federal, state, and local) government sector attract attention from politicians and the press when fiscal policy changes are under discussion. Government net lending equals tax receipts minus transfer payments and expenditure on goods and services. As shown below, such lending has been positive in just three years since 1982, corresponding to increasing government surpluses from 1998 to 2000. Economists began to wonder what would happen if the associated retirement of government debt—this is what happens when the government is a net lender—were to continue long enough to leave the financial system without any US Treasuries to hold as a safe asset against which to rank other assets. It turned out to be an “academic” question. Net lending by all branches of government turned negative in 2001, reached a peak of -$1.566 trillion in 2010, and then moved back towards zero. Government borrowing (the negative of net lending) was -$843 billion in 2017.

Source: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, NIPA Table 3.1, line 31

The National Income Accounting Identity keeps track of the relationship between the income and expenditure flows of three sectors: private, public, and foreign. If any sector is a net borrower, at least one other must be a net lender, as it is not possible for all to borrow or to lend. The “foreign sector” is the flip side of our current account balance, defined as exports minus imports plus net foreign income (which can be negative) minus US private and public transfers to the rest of the world. If the current account is negative, then the foreign sector has a surplus and so either the private sector or the public sector must have a deficit. This does not imply causation, but provides a coherent framework for discussion. Any policy change (such as tariffs on imports) intended to reduce the nation’s current account deficit will certainly fail unless that policy also increases either the private sector surplus or the government sector surplus (currently negative so that an increase means a smaller negative number).

Of the three sectoral balances, the government’s is the easiest to understand—tax receipts net of transfers (T) minus expenditure on goods and services (G), largely produced by the private sector (G also includes the salaries of government employees and military pay). The foreign sectoral balance is tricky only because it is the nation’s current account balance with the sign reversed. If the US has a current account deficit, then the foreign sector (the rest of the world) has a surplus with the US. The private sector balance requires more thought because of the definitions of “Saving” and “Investment” in the NIPA. Saving is defined as total private after-tax income from all sources (this year’s wages and salaries, rent, interest, and gross profit) minus consumption, which is household expenditure on currently produced durable and non-durable goods and services, except for residential structures. Investment in the NIPA is defined as residential and non-residential fixed investment plus the net change in business inventories. Non-residential (business) investment has three parts: structures (e.g. new factory buildings), equipment, and intellectual property products (e.g. new business software). Accordingly, if private sector saving (S), largely accounted for by the gross retained earnings of the business sector, exceeds investment (I), then the private sector runs a surplus and must be a net lender. Otherwise, it is a net borrower.

Four years of data for the US show various cases of lending and borrowing (in billions of current dollars). In 1965, a private surplus financed a government deficit and a foreign deficit (US current account surplus). In 2000, a private deficit was financed by a government surplus and a foreign surplus (US current account deficit). In 2006, a private deficit and a government deficit were financed by a foreign surplus. In 2016, a private surplus and a foreign surplus financed a government deficit. Note that the current account deficit (foreign surplus) and the government deficit are not necessarily “twins”, as is often suggested. Sometimes they move together, but not always, because the private sector surplus can also change. (In the table, the NIPA Statistical Error is subtracted from the Current Account to obtain, with sign reversed, an “Adjusted Foreign Surplus”. Government Investment in the NIPA is added to G and government depreciation allowances are added to T. These alterations ensure zero column sums for each year, to satisfy the National Income Accounting Identity.)

  1965 2000 2006 2016

Private Surplus: S – I 28.3 – 358 – 137 634
Government Surplus: T – G – 22.9 54 – 448 – 948
Adjusted Foreign Surplus – 5.4 304 585 314

 

A Primer on Stocks and Flows (Part 1)2018-07-04T19:37:45+00:00

May 04: Total Employment Increased by 164,000 in April, and the Unemployment Rate Edged Down to 3.9 Percent

Total nonfarm payroll employment increased by 164,000 in April, and the unemployment rate edged down to 3.9 percent, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today. Job gains occurred in professional and business services, manufacturing, health care, and mining. Read more

May 04: Total Employment Increased by 164,000 in April, and the Unemployment Rate Edged Down to 3.9 Percent2018-05-04T13:08:36+00:00

A Primer on Exchange Traded Funds: Costs and Benefits

Ernesto Garcia
April 30, 2018

Exchanged Traded Funds (ETFs) have been around since 1989. By the end of 2017, global ETF assets totaled $4.569 trillion. The main reason ETFs have become so popular is straightforward—an individual investor can own, through the ETF, a basket of assets that would otherwise be very expensive to replicate in the open market. Moreover, the assets in an ETF reflect the fund’s investment strategy, which usually does not change over the life of the fund. Individuals can effectively adopt the fund’s strategy, knowing it will not suddenly change in a way that no longer reflects his or her preferences concerning risk and return, sectoral and geographic balance, etc. ETFs are like mutual funds in this respect. In both cases, investors are considered passive—they are not actively buying and selling shares of stocks.

What separates ETFs from mutual funds is that, as the name suggests, ETFs are traded on exchanges like any other stock while mutual funds require membership in the institution that owns the fund. Another advantage is that ETFs require only a one-share investment while mutual funds restrict an investors’ minimum investment (almost always much higher than a single share of an ETF). Finally, and perhaps most importantly, mutual funds are only traded after the market closes, and this trade is done directly with the fund itself. ETFs are traded all day like any other stock. Thus, a mutual fund investor wanting to react quickly to intraday news, financial or otherwise, cannot do so. This can only be done at the end of the trading day while an ETF investor can buy or sell shares throughout the day.

How do ETFs Work?

ETFs are traded on exchanges just like individual equities and have similar attributes. Like stocks, they have a quoted price and a certain number of outstanding shares. Multiplying the price by the number of shares yields the market capitalization (market cap) of the ETF. Unlike the stock of a company, however, this market cap does not tell the full story of the value of an ETF’s shares. To understand why it is helpful to know how such shares are created.

Consider the SPDR (Standard and Poor Depository Receipts) S&P (Standard & Poor) 500 ETF Trust, known by its ticker symbol SPY. Owned and operated by S&P Global, it is the largest ETF in the world with an investment strategy that attempts to mirror movements in the S&P 500 index. If the S&P 500 index weights the stock of Apple at 3% of its value, then Apple will make up 3% of the basket of assets the SPY fund holds and similarly for all 500 components of the S&P.

However, ETFs do not purchase shares of stock (or other assets) directly in the open market. Rather, the ETF creates and redeems shares using an entity called an Authorized Participant (AP). Like a market maker, APs can buy and sell very large volumes of assets. The AP buys shares of the underlying assets on the open market and then the AP will trade this portfolio of underlying assets for shares of the ETF which the AP can then sell on the open market. In our example, S&P Global creates SPY shares while one or more APs purchase shares of companies included in the S&P 500 index. The AP will then exchange this portfolio of shares in the S&P 500 index for SPY shares in a process called creation. The opposite of creation is redemption. Redemption occurs when the AP purchases SPY shares in the open market and then exchanges these for a portfolio of shares corresponding to the S&P 500 index. These shares can then be sold by the AP in the open market and the redeemed ETF shares are retired. The AP chooses when they want to create or redeem shares of the ETF. This process of redemption and creation is what allows the ETF to be traded like ordinary shares of stock.

The price of ETF shares fluctuates during the trading day, just like any other ordinary share of stock, altering the market cap of the ETF. However, this is not necessarily the value of its underlying assets, or Assets Under Management (AUM), which also fluctuates during the trading day (since the underlying assets are individually traded on the open market). Such variation opens the possibility for profitable arbitrage, subject to transactions costs. Typically, APs are the largest potential arbitragers. Thus, if the market cap of the ETF falls below the corresponding AUM, a trader can buy low and sell high, purchasing ETF shares and simultaneously selling the corresponding AUM portfolio for a net gain. Few individual investors will act this way—they are, after all, typically passive investors. However, there is a segment of active investors in ETF funds constantly on the lookout for opportunities to buy low and sell high. This can be a good thing for the passive investors who count on the fact that the value of their ETF shares accurately reflects the value of the underlying shares they indirectly own.

Advantages of ETFs

The biggest advantage of an ETF for the typical retail investor is the low transaction costs associated with owning them. Fees paid for ETFs are generally much lower than those for mutual funds. Trading is also less costly since one pays the same amount to purchase a share of an ETF as it would cost to purchase the share of any company’s stock. Another advantage is that the minimum investment required is the price of one share of the ETF. This allows a retail investor to get the advantages of diversification at a price far lower than what it would cost to purchase the actual portfolio of underlying shares or the minimum investment required for a mutual fund. ETFs are traded throughout the day so retail investors can make investment decisions whenever the market is open rather than just at the end of the day as with mutual funds. Such trading allows arbitragers to keep the price of an ETF share close to the value of the underlying assets (AUM). Investors can also sell short or buy on margin.

Drawbacks of ETFs

While ETFs are intended to be passive investment instruments, the existence of active trading can be a source of instability. To highlight this, consider the following scenario. Currently, Apple shares constitute 4% of a SPY share. Suppose Apple reports unexpectedly low earnings causing the stock to sell off. The S&P 500 index only rebalances once every quarter, so even though Apple’s stock has fallen in price, Apple still maintains a 4% weight in the index and hence 4% of the SPY. Then, because the fall in the price of Apple’s stock lowers the value of the SPY’s underlying assets, it can cause SPY shares to be overvalued relative to the S&P 500 it is tracking. The AP, which holds a large number of shares of the SPY, will start selling the overvalued shares. A resulting price decline may cause other holders (such as retail investors) to start selling as well. If the price of SPY were to fall below its underlying asset, the AP will reverse direction, redeeming SPY shares from the fund for shares of the underlying stocks, and selling them on the open market. This, in turn, puts downward pressure on the price of those shares and so a cycle can develop even though SPY, like all ETFs, is meant to be a passive investment vehicle.

In our example, selling pressure on Apple’s stock has spread throughout the market via the seemingly passive ETF. Passive ETF investors usually ignore intraday fluctuations since they are long-term investors. However, ETFs allow for active trading and the process of creation and redemption together with active trading can lead to market contagion from a single stock’s price action. Since ETFs are such a large asset class now, this drawback cannot be ignored. Our Apple stock scenario could become more widespread especially as more investors purchase ETFs not knowing what the underlying assets are. Another concern that one must think about is events where market liquidity dries up. We assume arbitragers and the AP can simply buy and sell shares of the underlying ETF. But what if they cannot do it without causing a massive move in price?

An example of this occurred with the recent sell-off in the Daily Inverse VIX Short-Term ETN (Exchange Traded Note). ETNs are a type of unsecured, unsubordinated debt security and trade on exchanges just as ETFs do. The big similarity worth highlighting between the two is how retail investors easily trade them without much knowledge about trading debt. The VIX index (a popular measure of the stock market’s expectation of volatility implied by S&P 500 index options) increased by a large amount on February 5 of this year and caused the Daily Inverse VIX Short-Term ETN to drop over 80%. Not only did long-term investors in this ETN experience heavy loses, but there also appeared to be an associated overall market sell-off during the following week. While this was a leveraged ETN, it was very small compared to many of the other ETNs and ETFs in the market right now. What would happen if Apple experiences a major sell-off? These are questions that need to be raised and discussed as investor flows into ETFs continues to rise in the future.

A Primer on Exchange Traded Funds: Costs and Benefits2018-07-04T19:37:46+00:00
Go to Top