Technical Note: Federal Funds Rate Hike and Sovereign Risk in Latin America

Model

We conduct a country-by-country time series analysis of the government reaction function using impulse response of the country risk (Measured by the EMBIG) to an increase in de Federal Funds Rate. For this purpose, we part from a simple reaction function that we estimate for each country:

(1) st = α + Bit-1 + et where et ~ i.i.d.

Where s and i are, respectively, the country risk and the U.S. Federal Funds Rate. The latter is exogenously defined by the Federal Reserve.

Data and Methodology

The country risk variable is proxies with the EMBIG index, as explained in the main article. For this variable, the source of the data is the World Bank Economic Monitor. For the Federal Funds Rate, the source is FRED. We first test the stationarity of each variable. Tests reject non stationarity of all the first differenced series at the 95% confidence level.

The VAR lag order selection criteria indicates that 1 lag is optimal. Since for small samples, the AIC is more appropriate, we report its results for each country for different lags (Table 1). Both the Trace and maximum Eigenvalue tests in Johansen Full information Maximum Likelihood test suggests one cointegrating equation for different model assumptions concerning deterministic trends. We select the one with intercept and no trend in VAR.

Next, we proceed to build a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM), country by country, with one lag determined optimally as described above:

(3) Δyt = -Πyt-1 + ∑i=1 ΦjΔyt-i + ui,

Where yt =

[st, tt-1]’, Π = (I-∑i=1Ai) and Φi = -∑i=1Aj = -A(L).

Results

In Table 2 we report the long-run cointegration equations for each country.  For all of them, an increase in the Federal Funds rate generates an increase in the EMBIG. How do these results hold in the short run? To answer this we turn into impulse response functions, which are displayed in the second graph of the main article. The short-run results are consistent with the long-run ones: an increase in the Federal Funds Rate generate, on average, during the following next quarters, an increase in the country risk.

Table 1. AIC for each country 1 to 3 lags.

Country AIC 1 lags AIC 2 lags AIC 3 lags
Argentina 19.83 20.15 20.10
Brazil 17.35 17.50 17.48
Colombia 13.73 14.74 15.82
Mexico 14.31 14.62 15.50

 

Table 2. Vector Error Correction Models.

 Cointegrating Eq:   CointEq1
 FEDRATE(-1)   1.000000
 EMBIG_ARG(-1)  -0.002028
    (0.00082)
   [-2.46806]
 C   0.381888
Cointegrating Eq:  CointEq1
EMBIG_BRA(-1) 1.000000
FEDRATE(-1) -143.4935
  (39.1876)
  [-3.66171]
C -144.2223
Cointegrating Eq:  CointEq1
EMBIG_COL(-1) 1.000000
FEDRATE(-1) -102.1662
  (20.8519)
  [-4.89961]
C -88.09853
Cointegrating Eq:  CointEq1
FEDRATE(-1)  1.000000
EMBIG_MEX(-1) -0.037714
   (0.00541)
  [-6.97417]
C  6.930402

Note: The table displays the estimation results of the cointegrations equation for, respectively, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico. 

Technical Note: Federal Funds Rate Hike and Sovereign Risk in Latin America2018-07-04T19:37:49+00:00

September 01: Total Employment Increased by 156,000 in August, and the Unemployment Rate Was Little Changed at 4.4 Percent

Total nonfarm payroll employment increased by 156,000 in August, and the unemployment rate was little changed at 4.4 percent, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today. Job gains occurred in manufacturing, construction, professional and technical services, health care, and mining. Read more

September 01: Total Employment Increased by 156,000 in August, and the Unemployment Rate Was Little Changed at 4.4 Percent2017-09-01T16:25:26+00:00

Federal Funds Rate Hike and Sovereign Risk in Latin America

Miguel Acosta-Henao
August 31, 2017

The Fed has started increasing the federal funds rate, reversing its decade long accommodative monetary policy.  The last time such a reversal in the Fed policy occurred, the impact on emerging markets in Latin America was deleterious. This article examines if history will repeat itself. 

By the end of the 1970s the most important Latin American economies had opened their capital accounts to the rest of the world and received a considerable amount of capital inflows that were financing sovereign debt.  However, this ended when the Federal Reserve (FED), led by Paul Volcker, pursued a sharp disinflation, increasing the federal funds rate, and resulting in high capital outflows from emerging markets to the U.S. These flows caused long currency depreciations and increased the risk premium of sovereign bonds in those countries. As a result, as documented by Krugman (2009), Mexico, Argentina and Brazil went into technical default, capital inflows ceased,  inflation sky rocketed (especially in Argentina) and these economies, as well as the rest of the region, entered into deep recessions that took a severe toll on Latin America’s potential growth through the 1980s.   

Currently, ten years after the start of the great recession, inflation is converging to the FED’s 2% target and the labor market in the U.S. continues giving signals of strength–an unemployment rate of 4.3% and a payroll job growth matching the growth before the start of the crisis in 2007. These facts have led the FED to increase the federal fund’s rate and to announce more hikes during this year.

Latin American countries are not as indebted as they were at the beginning of the 1980s (except for Venezuela) nor do they have the same weak macroeconomic institutions they had in the past. Economic fragilities, however, exist.  Between 2003 and 2013 Latin America received a considerable amount of foreign investment. Unlike the 1970s, however, it was in the form of gross capital formation directed to the commodities sector (mainly oil). This meant that governmental borrowing was not as significant as it was thirty years ago. Nevertheless, a reversal of capital flows would still affect the whole external debt of the region, whether is public or private, due to currency depreciation and a negative effect on each economy’s sovereign risk, which could lead these countries to the brink of a recession. One part of this process has already started following the commodity price shocks, with average currency depreciations of 30% between 2014 and 2017 for Mexico, Brazil, Colombia, Chile, and Peru.

Sovereign Risk in Latin America

The benchmark estimate of country interest rate spreads for emerging markets is J.P Morgan’s Emerging Market Bond Index Global, EMBIG.  The Index, which compares a composite of bonds with different maturities and liquidities in each country with a similar composite for the U.S, reflects sovereign risk in those countries, is available starting in 1994 for selected Latin American countries. Figure 1 shows both the evolution of the EMBIG from 1994 for the most representative emerging countries in Latin America (excluding Venezuela), and of the federal funds rate during the same period.

Figure 1: EMBIG Selected Latin American economies (basis points).

Between 1998 and 2001, most Latin American economies suffered deep recessions that started with the increase in their sovereign risks, as it can be seen in the graph. But, in line with the massive capital inflows that the region received between 2003 and 2013, the EMBIG of each country substantially decreased during those years.  It has risen modestly recently, although not at all close to the levels seen before the year 2002.

Impact of the FED Funds Rate on Sovereign Risk in Latin America

For each country, we estimate an econometric model that allows us to see the response of each country’s sovereign risk to the FED’s rate hike. For each country in the sample, Figure 2 shows the response of sovereign risk to a 100 basis point increase in the federal funds rate.

Figure 2: EMBIG response to a to 100 points increase in the federal funds rate (basis points).

Figure 2 presents the results of our estimation, which show a large and sustained response of interest rates in each of the countries to a rise in the U.S. federal funds rate.  These results are in line with those of Uribe and Yue (2006), who show that for a group of emerging markets, an increase in federal funds rate leads country spreads to fall and then display a large, delayed overshooting.  Clearly, the results are alarming: an interest rate hike in the U.S. has a permanent negative effect over the country risk for Latin America, let alone a continuous path of interest rate hikes like the one the FED plans to do.

Will history repeat itself?

Contrary to the episode in the 1980s, most Latin American countries have central banks with full independence and explicit inflation targets. External debt as a share of GDP is, on average, less than 70% compared to the 3-digit numbers in the 1980s. Some countries like Colombia have explicit fiscal rules that contribute to smooth the cycle through fiscal policy while committing to keep the public deficit within a defined range. However, it doesn’t mean that the region is completely shielded against the FED’s hike. The increase in country risk compromises investment in countries that still lack physical infrastructure to compete with other emerging countries such as China or a number in South East Asia; the volatility that this brings to the business cycle contributes an increase in uncertainty about the future and may generate misallocation of capital among investors, and pressures over governments to raise taxes and reduce government spending (in order to avoid a down grade in their risk rating) may imply fiscal reforms that seriously slows down (or even contract) the growth rate of the GDP in those countries.

It is then important that not only governments but also central banks among those countries prepare themselves correctly for what may come. Recent literature has pointed out the importance of capital controls in booms and busts as a potential tool to help reduce the volatility of the business cycle. Also, imminent tax reforms like the one Colombia had during 2016 (which aimed to increased tax revenue) could be complemented with institutional reforms that contribute to improving productivity, which has been Latin America’s longer-term problem as shown by Restuccia (2013). All in all, the main point is that, even though the region seems more prepared than before to a FED’s hike, it is still vulnerable according to our empirical analysis; therefore, the region should consider new policy tools as well as important structural reforms to reduce the exposure that it has to foreign interest rate shocks.

 

Federal Funds Rate Hike and Sovereign Risk in Latin America2018-07-04T19:37:49+00:00

August 30: Revised Q2 GDP Growth Came in Higher Than Expected at 3%

Real gross domestic product increased 3.0 percent in the second quarter of 2017, according to the “second” estimate released by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. The growth rate was 0.4 percentage point more than the “advance” estimate released in July. In the first quarter, real GDP increased 1.2 percent. Read more

August 30: Revised Q2 GDP Growth Came in Higher Than Expected at 3%2018-07-04T19:37:49+00:00

August 17: The New York State Department of Labor reported that more than 21,000 jobs were added in the state in July.

The New York State Department of Labor reported that more than 21,000 jobs were added in the state in July.  Over the past year total state employment is up 1.5 percent, matching the 1.5 percent job growth rate nationwide.  Growth in the state was helped by a strong expansion of jobs in New York City. Read more. 
August 17: The New York State Department of Labor reported that more than 21,000 jobs were added in the state in July.2017-08-22T19:57:37+00:00

Export Growth and Aggregate Dynamics in Large Devaluations

George Alessandria, University of Rochester and NBER; Sangeeta Pratap, Hunter College and the Graduate Center, CUNY; Vivian Yue, Emory University, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and NBER
May 2015

Why do exports not increase immediately after an exchange rate devaluation? This is an important question, because export dynamics have important consequences for growth and capital flows. We trace the dynamic path of exports after 11 large devaluations in emerging economies and find that they they peak in around three years after the devaluation.  The extensive margin plays an important role in these dynamics, i.e. the increase in exports is largely fueled by exports of new products and by new firms.  We also find that interest rates are important: export growth was more sluggish in episodes where interest rates also increased.

We explain these facts using a simple insight: Entering in an export market often requires a firm to incur very specific costs such as product standardization, certification, etc. which are independent of the scale of production. Such costs play an important role in explaining firm dynamics. In particular, a large devaluation may make it more profitable to export, but it takes time to build export capacity. An increase in interest rates makes it more expensive to amortize these costs and acts as a disincentive to exports.

Using this simple idea, we build a framework to measure the impact of devaluations, and the associated economic crises, on exports, capital flows and output in emerging economies. We find that these export specific costs lead to deeper contractions and stronger recoveries.

Working paper

Export Growth and Aggregate Dynamics in Large Devaluations2018-07-04T19:37:49+00:00

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations: Effects on Loans and Systemic Risk, Deposits, and Borrowing

Forthcoming in National Tax Journal, September 2017
Timothy J. Goodspeed
, Hunter College and Graduate Center, CUNY

A particularly important risk in the financial sector that is often discussed as one of the reasons for the recent collapse of the financial system is that the banks invested in overly risky loan portfolios, particularly those related to the housing market. The riskiness of a bank’s loan portfolio, especially loans related to the housing market, is an important source of instability in the financial system.

I develop a simple model of banks that includes financial regulations and systemic risk and examine various options for the taxation of banks. The model emphasizes systemic risk in a bank’s loan decisions and thus debt in the economy as whole rather than a particular bank’s debt to equity ratio. An externality arises because a bank’s loan decisions affect the economy-wide probability of loan success. The bank takes account of the effect of its loan decisions on itself but ignores the effects on other banks in the system.

The model is utilized to examine the effects of five possible taxes (on bank loans, deposits, liabilities, equity, and profits).  Each tax has particular impacts on the market for loans and deposits, and consequent effects on interbank borrowing and the riskiness of a bank’s loan portfolio. All of the taxes except the tax on deposits will decrease the supply of loans and the riskiness of loans in the economy. The tax on deposits does not affect either of these variables due to the assumption of separability of the management costs of deposits and loans. All of the taxes will decrease a bank’s demand for deposits except the tax on loans, again due to the separability assumption.  A bank’s borrowing will rise with the tax on deposits, fall with the tax on loans, and will be indeterminate for the other taxes.

I discuss extensions to consider depositor access to international capital markets and tax avoidance by multinational banks. Results for the former case will depend on the degree of substitutability between deposits and funds in international capital markets. An interesting result for the latter case is that tax avoidance by multinational banks tends to increase the riskiness of a bank’s loan portfolio in some cases.

Working paper

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations: Effects on Loans and Systemic Risk, Deposits, and Borrowing2018-07-04T19:37:49+00:00

The Eurozone Convergence Through Crises and Structural Changes

Merih Uctum, Brooklyn College and the Graduate Center, CUNY; Remzi Uctum, Universite de Paris Ouest; Chu-Ping C. Vijverberg, College of Staten Islands and the Graduate Center, CUNY 
July 2017

Despite the recent resurgence in the European economies, the 2008 U.S. financial crisis that caused a global recession also pushed many of them, in particular, those in the periphery, into a stubborn recession, which led to the rise of populist political movements.  The severity of the crisis is seen as an indictment of the European Monetary Union for failing to generate convergence to its members.  Convergence is crucial for the conduct of the single monetary policy where members do not have recourse to fiscal transfer mechanisms nor currency adjustments.   In this paper, we examine whether the process towards monetary union and the common experience of the euro, the single European currency, led to the convergence of output growth for member countries and if shocks to the economies affected it.

The skepticism about the promises of the European Monetary Union goes back to its conception, which occurred among intense controversy about whether the Eurozone was ready to become a currency union since it was not satisfying the original criteria of the Optimal Currency Area. Subsequent studies of currency unions showed a significantly deepened trade integration among member countries of a monetary union.  The implication is that the Optimal Currency Area criteria can be satisfied after unification resulting in trade integration and income convergence. The endogenous business cycle synchronization argument draws on two linkages: If a currency union increases trade, which, in turn, leads to synchronization of business cycles, then it is argued that business cycles are synchronized “endogenously”.  Empirical results are not uniform though several support the argument of increased synchronization through trade.  However, these results are challenged by the view that business cycles in Europe are affected by many factors, which are mostly ignored except the trade channel but can decrease output co-movements in the union and their exclusion could lead to potentially biased results. 

Convergence is a process that takes place over an extended period, disrupted by crises and recessions, speeding up during recovery and booms.  The existing analyses that rely on panel methodologies are neither sufficiently long enough nor suitable to capture such non-linear processes.  Our paper investigates output growth converge in the European Monetary Union from an angle different than the existing literature.  We exploit the time series characteristics of several economies in the European Union and examine if output growth in the peripheral countries converged towards that of the core countries. The higher the elasticity of peripheral countries growth to that of core countries, the greater the synchronization between the core and the periphery.  By using a novel methodology we are able to account for reverse causality and structural changes created by policy and crises, which are mostly ignored in the literature. 

Therefore, the evidence we uncover does not support the view that the switch to euro would generate a closer integration of the markets and thus automatically synchronize growth rates between the peripherals and the core countries. However, our results support the view that the preparations towards the creation of the single currency spurred convergence among several countries in the region well before the introduction of the euro, and continued after that.  Once the last ripple effects of the Great Recession subside, Europe should see a greater synchronization in the member economies, with possible beneficial impact on the political process.

Working paper

The Eurozone Convergence Through Crises and Structural Changes2018-07-04T19:37:50+00:00

How Bad Will It Be If We Hit the Debt Ceiling?

Paul Krugman
August 19, 2017

The odds of a self-inflicted US debt crisis now look pretty good: hard-line Republicans are eager to hold the economy hostage, Democrats are in no mood to make concessions, and Trump is both spiteful and ignorant. So it looks fairly likely that by October or so there will come a day when the U.S. government stops paying some of its bills, including interest on debt.

How bad will that be? The truth is that we don’t know; but it may be helpful to talk about *why* we don’t know.

Until now, US debt has played a special role in the world economy, because it is — or was — the ultimate safe asset, the thing people can use to secure transactions with no questions about it retaining its value. In a way, the dollar is to other moneys as money is to other assets, and US dollar debt is the form in which dollars are held with ultimate safety.

Taking away that role could be very nasty. One prominent interpretation of the 2008 financial crisis is that it was a “safe asset shortage“, pushing safe real interest rates to negative territories:

Source: IMF (2014)

When people realized that those AAA securities engineered from subprime loans weren’t the real thing, they scrambled into an inadequate supply of trill safe stuff. Deprive them of dollar debts as safe assets, and terrible things could happen.

The question then becomes whether an interruption in payments would really knock out the special role of U.S. debt.

Suppose that everyone expected normal payments to resume, with back interest, in a couple of weeks. In that case, even a slight discount on, say, Treasury bills would make them a very good investment — so speculators would basically step in and support the value of U.S. debt despite temporary default. In that case default might not be that big a deal.

The big problem would come if investors see the default as more than a temporary glitch — if they see it as a sign of enduring, critical dysfunction in American governance. In that case they wouldn’t necessarily step in to buy our debt, and their confidence in the whole economic edifice would take a severe hit.

How Bad Will It Be If We Hit the Debt Ceiling?2018-07-04T19:37:50+00:00

August 04: Total Employment Increased by 209,00 in July, and the Unemployment Rate Was Little Changed at 4.3 Percent

Total nonfarm payroll employment increased by 209,000 in July, and the unemployment rate was little changed at 4.3 percent, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today. Employment increased in food services and drinking places, professional and business services, and health care. Read more

August 04: Total Employment Increased by 209,00 in July, and the Unemployment Rate Was Little Changed at 4.3 Percent2017-08-18T17:58:17+00:00
Go to Top