How Should We Think About the Effects of Corporate Tax Cuts?

Paul Krugman
February 08, 2018

Late last year Republicans enacted a huge tax cut, mainly for corporations. They then seized on some seemingly supportive data points – investment announcements by some major corporations, bonuses paid to some employees, an uptick in some measures of wage growth – as evidence that the cut was already benefiting workers. But while there is a case for cutting corporate taxes, the logic of that case says that any benefits to workers should unfold gradually over time, not show up in a few weeks.

And there is also a case against corporate tax cuts, even aside from the fact that revenue must be raised somewhere, and getting less from profit taxes means either raising other taxes or cutting spending.

The purpose of this note is to lay out a stylized framework for thinking about these issues. There exist carefully specified general-equilibrium models for tax incidence, but my sense is that there’s not enough intuition in these models for them to play as large a role in the discussion as they should. So, I’m going to present a slightly different approach, one that I described in a somewhat disconnected series of blog posts over the course of the tax debate. Here I try to collect it into a unified, comprehensible narrative.

1. The simple analytics of trickle-down

Imagine that we had a one-sector economy with no monopoly power, open to inflows of foreign capital. In reality, the economy is characterized by considerable monopoly rents, most of the capital stock isn’t in the corporate sector, and most of GDP is nontradable. These complications all weaken the extent to which corporate tax cuts trickle down to wages. But let’s give some hostages here, and consider the most favorable case.

Such a stylized economy would look like Figure 1. The downward-sloping line is the marginal product of capital, which is equal (in this model) to the pre-tax rate of return r. The after-tax return is r(1-t), where t is the tax rate. Given an initial capital stock K, GDP is the integral of the area under the r curve up to K. Of this, rK goes to pre-tax profits, of which the government takes a share t and the rest goes to after-tax profits. What’s left, the triangle at the top, is wages.


Figure 1

Now, the key justification being offered for corporate tax cuts is that the U.S. is the international mobility of capital: reducing U.S. taxes will, supposedly, draw in investment from abroad, either from U.S. corporations bringing money home or foreign corporations buying into the U.S. economy. We can capture this effect by adding a supply curve for capital, as in Figure 2.

For a small open economy, this supply curve would be horizontal in the long run. It is, however, surely upward-sloping for the United States.

Now suppose the corporate tax rate is cut to a lower level t’. This raises the after-tax rate of return for any given capital stock. Over time the capital stock rises to K’. This in turn leads to higher wages.

Figure 2

The crucial words, however, are “over time.” For a variety of reasons, it would take a number of years for the capital stock to rise to its long-run level.

What are these reasons? One is that adjusting the capital stock would take time even if purely domestic factors were involved: a large increase in capital formation would drive up the wages of construction workers, the rent on construction equipment, the prices of commodities used in construction, etc. This is why we don’t expect Tobin’s q to be one all the time.

Beyond this, we’re talking about capital inflows here, which would have to have as their counterpart an expanded trade deficit, effected via a temporarily strong dollar. And this temporary strength of the dollar would in itself be a deterrent to capital inflows, since investors would expect it to go back down again.

The bottom line is that the short-run supply curve of capital should be more or less vertical; full trickle-down should happen only in the long run, where this run is measured in a number of years. Whatever cherry-picked good news comes in the first few weeks after a corporate tax cut is, almost by definition, irrelevant to the case for that cut.

2. Long-run welfare effects

Since the capital stock is effectively fixed in the short run, the short-run incidence and welfare effects of a corporate tax cut are simple: no change in real income, all the gains go to owners of capital. In the long run, however, the capital stock does rise. So, what are the effects?

Again, as a starting point we can think of a downward-sloping demand for capital, reflecting its marginal product. We can also think of an upward-sloping supply of capital, with the upward slope reflecting both the size of the US — we’re probably around half of the world’s capital market not subject to capital controls — and the imperfect nature of capital mobility, even now.

For current purposes it’s helpful to focus not on the corporate tax rate per se but rather on the wedge corporate taxes place between the rate of return to capital before taxes — which is assumed equal to its marginal product — and the after-tax return received by investors. This does not mean changing the model, it’s just a way of presenting the picture that bypasses some messy algebra that can (and has) led some economists to make errors. So, we think of the corporate profits tax as being kind of like an excise tax on capital, as shown in Figure 3.

Figure 3

Notice that I’ve indicated here the reality that a significant fraction of the current capital stock is owned by foreigners. This is a big deal: gross U.S. liabilities to the rest of the world are around 1.7 times GDP, and around 35 percent of corporate equity is foreign-owned. As we’ll see in a minute, it matters for the welfare analysis.

What happens if we cut corporate taxes? We reduce the size of the corporate tax wedge, which brings in more capital from abroad and raises GDP. But it doesn’t raise GNP – the income of domestic residents – by the same amount, for two reasons. First, the additional capital doesn’t come free: we have to pay foreigners for the use of the additional capital (or get less income from investments abroad if it’s U.S. capital coming home.) Second, we pay a higher rate of return on the foreign capital already here. So net international investment income falls, offsetting at least part of the rise in GDP. In fact, the fall in investment income could be larger than the rise in output, so that national income actually falls.

Figure 4 tells the slightly intricate story, for a small change in the tax rate (so we can ignore triangles):

Figure 4

The lower tax rate shrinks the wedge, leading to a higher capital stock, lower pre-tax rate of return, and higher wages. The green rectangle at the top is the part of the tax cut that’s passed through to increased wages. As long as the supply curve for capital is upward-sloping, it also leads to higher after-tax returns to capital, with the gains partly accruing to domestic investors, partly to foreign investors. These gains are offset by a loss of revenue.

The possibility of overall gains to the U.S. economy comes from the fact that we started with a wedge: the rate of return on investment, equal to the pre-tax return on capital, was larger than the cost of capital from abroad, equal to the after-tax return. So, bringing in more capital produces a net gain equal to the change in the capital stock times that wedge – the yellow rectangle at the right.

Notice, however, that this is a lot smaller than the rise in GDP, which is the whole pre-tax return times the rise in the capital stock. Since the initial tax rate was 35%, the gain to the U.S. should be only 0.35 times whatever gain we get in GDP.

And that’s without taking into account the extra payments to foreign capital already here – the red rectangle at the lower right. Back of the envelope calculations suggest that once we take that into account, any net gains are very small, and maybe negative.

One way to think about all this is that because the U.S. is a big player in world capital markets, and already effectively employs a lot of foreign capital, we effectively have considerable monopsony power in world capital markets. When we cut corporate taxes, we end up attracting more foreign capital but paying the capital we already employ more. This analysis shows that it is not at all clear that the cut in corporate tax rates works in our favor, which makes the case for the tax bill just enacted look remarkably weak.

How Should We Think About the Effects of Corporate Tax Cuts?2018-07-04T19:37:47+00:00

February 02: Total Non-Farm Payroll Employment Increased by 200,000 in January

Total nonfarm payroll employment increased by 200,000 in January, and the unemployment rate was unchanged at 4.1 percent, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today. Employment continued to trend up in construction, food services and drinking places, health care, and manufacturing. Read more

February 02: Total Non-Farm Payroll Employment Increased by 200,000 in January2018-02-20T14:13:29+00:00

Dream Hoarders: Is the Upper Middle Class Leaving Everyone Else Behind?

Andreas Kakolyris
January 30, 2018

On November 15, 2017, the City University of New York Graduate Center and the Stone Center on Socio-Economic Inequality co-hosted a presentation by Richard Reeves, Senior Fellow at the Brookings Institution, on the topic Dream Hoarders: Is the Upper Middle Class Leaving Everyone Else Behind The presentation focused on the widening gap between those in the top quintile of the income distribution and the remaining 80 percent and was based on Reeves’ latest book Dream Hoarders: How the American Upper Middle Class is Leaving Everyone Else in the Dust, Why That is a Problem and What to Do About It. The presentation was followed by a panel discussion with panelists Janet Gornick, Paul Krugman, and Leslie McCall of the Stone Center and Miles Corak of the University of Ottawa (who will be joining the faculty of the Graduate Center Economics Program in January).

Reeves opened the event with a summary of the key points in his book. He argued that the United States has a class system that, unlike the United Kingdom, is not widely recognized. Class consciousness can help the members of a society become more aware of class divisions and create more political room for tackling inequality. A second point is related to the more traditional division between the top one percent of the income distribution and the bottom ninety-nine percent. The author claims that the focus of the inequality debate on this gap is unhelpful and allows people belonging even to the 99th percentile of the income distribution to believe that inequality is the fault of rich people, more specifically, of an ambiguously defined set of people; the people who are richer than them. In his work, Reeves defines the upper middle class as those in the top quintile of the income distribution. He emphasizes the important role of education in replicating class inequality and the sense of entitlement and the hoarding of opportunities by those in this upper quintile, including exclusionary housing zoning, legacy admissions, and internship opportunities. He stresses the need for change in the U.S. political culture that allows a system of entitlement at the top of the society. Reeves uses the example of the squelching of the attempt made by President Barack Obama to limit the tax benefits of a savings plan (520 plans) that helps families pay for the cost of college as an illustration of the political power of the American upper middle class. This group of people, which is in the top quintile of household income, is well organized and numerous enough to be a serious voting bloc and able to control many critical institutions. In his concluding remarks, Reeves spotlights the dimensions of well-being that play a role in class reproduction, among them wealth, health, parenting, life expectancy, neighborhood, and education.

Following the presentation, panel moderator Janet Gornick raised a number of questions related to the zero-sum framework where in order for someone to win, someone else has to lose. Whereas Gornick agrees with the problematic focus on the top 1%, she expresses her concern regarding the right place to draw the fault line and whether the top quintile is the basis of the “elite” group. She also suggests more attention should be given to the intra- and inter-generationally absolute income mobility, and how to tackle class inequality and move the framework from a zero-sum game. The expansion of the middle class, defined as those whose income falls in a band around the median, would make a contribution to this end. In addition, she raises the issue of whether there are policies that could support the increase in the share of households whose members enjoy the other “positives” associated with the top fifth, such as access to quality health care and education. She also emphasizes the large difference in the United States compared to other countries between the 20th and 80th percentiles of the income distribution.

Miles Corak presented data on the issue of the relationship of dream hoarding and inter-generationally income mobility. He presents geographically disaggregated income mobility data that show that in communities where the probability of being born in the top quintile of the income distribution and staying there are high, it is more likely for poor people to become rich. On the other hand, in communities where the inter-generational cycle of poverty is high, we observe that is really hard for poor people to become rich. The challenge is really how to break out of the bottom of the distribution. He also brought up the issue of changes in peoples’ behavior resulting from the observation of groups of people who are much better than them as well as groups of people who are much lower than them. As the last point, Corak wonders whether the political agenda proposed in the book is utopic, for example, is there a political program that could support the people of upper middle class to not only fight for the best for their children, but also to have their energy and drive help others.

Paul Krugman addresses the issue raised by Gornick about the right setting of the fault line that would define an “elite” group in the society. He doubts the existence of such a line due to the growing inequality between any two points of the income distribution and raises the question of whether the group of people from 80th to 99th percentile could be considered as a unique social class. He presents data that show a strong pulling apart of the income distribution at the 99th percentile, and above, and also expresses some doubts about the political dominance with an example showing that the current tax legislation increases the relative amount of taxes paid by dream hoarders.

Leslie McCall sheds more light on the political dimension and characteristics of the upper middle class. She agrees with the expansion of the political focus to a broader group than the top 1%, and proposes to shift attention from the white working class to the middle/upper class, that according to her is the real impediment to greater equality. McCall also proposes the political agenda to be focused on opportunity-enhancing policies rather than general tax and transfer policies. She concludes that the reduction of market inequality would reduce economic anxiety that feeds dream hoarding.

Reeves made several points in response to a number of the issues raised by the panelists. First, he continues the discussion about the answer as to the appropriate measurement of the inequality gap. He refers to a graph used by Krugman which shows that, although the average annual growth of income for the 80th percentile is roughly equal to the average, the pulling apart of the distribution starts there. Reeves notes that Corak’s comments showing the important features of geographic inequality is very interesting and takes an interesting perspective, as presented in the book, on the zero-sum framework.

In a follow-up comment, Krugman reiterates a point made by other panelists that extreme inequality as observed for income, access to health or access to good education create a war feeling in our society. Thus, the hoarding of the dream can be thought of as a reaction to the extreme inequality of the society in that the alternative for not hoarding the dream can be costly.

Reeves closed the event by taking questions from the audience.

Dream Hoarders: Is the Upper Middle Class Leaving Everyone Else Behind?2018-07-04T19:37:47+00:00

A Primer on Rules of Origin in NAFTA Negotiations and What Is Next

Richard J Nugent III
December 22, 2017

The latest round of negotiations of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) on November 21 ended with no major breakthroughs on contentious issues such as autos, dairy and rules of origin among others. The US administration’s demand that at least half of a NAFTA-qualifying vehicle should be made in the US and 85 percent in North America met stiff resistance from Canada and Mexico. Compromise on rules of origin for the North American automotive industry will matter for the successful renegotiation of NAFTA.

What is rules of origin (ROO) and why do we need it?

NAFTA ROO can be loosely defined as a set of rules that are used to determine whether a good can be considered as being made in North America. If this is the case, then these goods are typically exempt from tariff when traded between two North American countries. Article 401 of the Agreement defines “originating” in four ways: (i) goods wholly obtained in the NAFTA region; (ii) goods meeting the Annex 401 origin rule on specific ROO; (iii) goods produced entirely in the NAFTA region from originating materials; (iv) disassembled goods and goods described with their parts that do not meet the Annex 401 specific ROO but contain 60 percent NAFTA content in transaction value. Article 403.5.a increases the value-content requirement for motor vehicles to 62.5 percent. The Trump administration has proposed increasing this requirement to 85% and adding a 50% U.S.-specific value-content requirement for motor vehicles. This would require a larger portion of the motor vehicle production process to be sourced within the region and in the United States, particularly.

The use of ROO are in principle to deter trade deflection. The objective is to prevent resources from being sourced from a country outside a free-trade region for assembly inside the region and later exported at preferential tariff rates within the free-trade region. If for example a can opener is assembled in Mexico from parts that are made in Brazil, the origin of this can opener is Brazil. Were this can opener exported to Canada or the United States, it would be subject to MFN tariffs as opposed to NAFTA preferential tariff rates.

NAFTA eliminates tariffs on most goods originating in Canada, Mexico, and the United States. The ROO for goods that are not wholly obtained from the NAFTA region are based on a tariff-shift method, regional value-content method, or technical process test:

  • Under the tariff-shift method, a product earns preferential treatment under NAFTA if it has a different Harmonized Tariff System classification than its imported inputs for a particular statistical level. This means a product can earn NAFTA-origin status if it has been modified substantially within a NAFTA country.
  • The value-content method requires a good traded within the region to contain at least 50 to 60 percent NAFTA content to obtain origin status.
  • Technical process tests can require incorporation of specific parts or require a particular method of assembly. Technical process tests are found in machinery and equipment manufacturing and the apparel and textiles industry. A common technical process test used in the apparel and textile industry is “yarn-forward.” Yarn-forward requires the yarn that is used to make fabric be spun in the NAFTA region. Thus, cotton that is imported from Pakistan to Mexico, spun into cotton yarn, and later used to make slacks can be exported to the United States at preferential NAFTA rates. “Yarn-forward” observes Mexico as these pants’ origin. However, if the cotton is spun into yarn in Pakistan and then imported into Mexico where it is used to make the slacks, the origin of the slacks is now Pakistan.

How do the ROO work?

We can answer this question by reviewing examples of tariff classification and origin rulings issued by the U.S. Department for Customs and Border Patrol. In 2004, a U.S. producer sought to import wiper blade arms from Mexico, which were made with a “non- originating” flat-coated wire. This piece might have disqualified the wiper blade arm from NAFTA preferential treatment. However, the Mexican supplier substantially modified the wire: it was imported into Mexico under Chapter 72 and exported to the United States under subheading 8512.90 as a part of the wiper blade arm, which is qualified for preferential treatment under NAFTA. In 2010, a Canadian producer sought to export vehicle door locks. The door locks were assembled in Canada using components made exclusively in China and Germany. No component of the door lock originated in Canada. As such, the locks did not qualify for preferential treatment under NAFTA, and the rate of duty assigned to the locks was 5.7 percent.

How do ROO impact trade?

ROO exist to protect the interests of the countries participating in a multilateral free trade agreement, but could potentially distort trade flows. Distortions are particularly pervasive where global supply chains are big players in shaping the way trade occurs between two countries. The role of supply chains increases with the prevalence of global value chains in international trade. Studies have demonstrated that the expansion of these value chains means that production has become increasingly fragmented and supply chains are being vertically integrated across countries. Many firms in different countries are taking part in particular stages of the production process, together forming a global supply chain. This form of fragmented production results in intermediate inputs crossing international borders several times before final delivery. ROO therefore have rigid and costly implications for the way goods are produced and traded in global markets. Where global supply chains exist partially outside of a free trade agreement, a change in ROO could be potentially deleterious. When goods cross multiple borders or cross borders multiple times as in the fragmented production processes, they are exposed to more trade costs which can accumulate and compound before the goods are sold for final consumption. Thus, production which is labeled non-originating by a change in ROO can be very costly.

A study on how the characteristics of U.S. industries helped to shape NAFTA ROO finds that industries characterized by larger returns to scale sought tougher ROO, while industries dependent on global supply chains sought more permissive ROO. Firms that face ROO decide whether to comply with the rules so as to export at preferential tariff rates, or to not comply with the rules and source inputs unconditionally. Researchers who study this decision by Mexican firms find that the ROO for final goods led to a 115 percentage point reduction in imports of intermediaries from non-NAFTA countries after the implementation of NAFTA.

ROO are a useful component of free trade agreements in their role to prevent trade deflection. However, the rules can be exploited in the objective of industry protection and can potentially distort trade flows. Additionally, if ROO are changed in a way that disrupts global supply chains, the costs of delivering some goods could mount considerably. Furthermore, if the parties renegotiating NAFTA stand firm regarding the motor vehicles regional content requirement, the future of NAFTA could be in a precarious place.

A Primer on Rules of Origin in NAFTA Negotiations and What Is Next2018-07-04T19:37:47+00:00

December 21: U.S. GDP Rose 3.2 Percent in Q3, Revised Downward from 3.3 Percent

Real gross domestic product (GDP) increased at an annual rate of 3.2 percent in the third quarter of 2017, according to the “third” estimate released by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. The GDP estimate released today is based on more complete source data than were available for the “second” estimate issued last month. In the second estimate, the increase in real GDP was 3.3 percent. With this third estimate for the third quarter, personal consumption expenditures increased less than previously estimated, but the general picture of economic growth remains the same. Read more

 
December 21: U.S. GDP Rose 3.2 Percent in Q3, Revised Downward from 3.3 Percent2018-07-04T19:37:47+00:00

December 01: the New York State Department of Labor Reported a Loss of 14,000 Jobs Statewide in October

The New York State Department of Labor reported a loss of 14,000 jobs statewide in October, following revised job losses of 15,000 in September. Total employment is up 1.1% in the state over a year ago compared to 1.4% for the nation. The Bureau of Labor Statistics reported that New York City gained 19,000 jobs in October, more than offsetting losses of 15,000 jobs in September. Employment in the city is up 1.5% over a year ago. Read more

December 01: the New York State Department of Labor Reported a Loss of 14,000 Jobs Statewide in October2017-12-01T23:42:44+00:00

Why Does It Still Not Feel Like Recovery? A Look at Industry Performance

The Economic Studies Group
November 30, 2017

The recovery of activity following the Great Recession got off to a slow start compared to previous cycles. The recession was characterized by deep declines in output (GDP) and the largest increases in the unemployment rate since the 1930s, and it wasn’t until six years into the recovery that the level of aggregate real GDP returned to its potential. In this post, we look at the growth of output in individual industries since the recovery began. While the performance has varied, many industries have also shown a relatively weak recovery, particularly when compared to previous cycles. The analysis indicates that industries are in quite different situations as the economy enters a period of rising interest rates.

The Aggregate Economy

The figure below plots an index of annual real GDP from the formally designated start of the recovery in 2009 (year 0 in the chart) to 2016 and, for comparison, a similar index of real output in the first seven years of previous recoveries. The figure shows that seven years since the downturn ended real GDP is up only 15 percent from the trough. This growth is relatively weak compared to the recovery from the early 2000s recession and to an average of the recoveries in the 1980s and 1990s.

Data Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and ESG Calculations

All cycles are different, of course, and the recent recession was preceded by a buildup of unsustainable levels of debt, particularly housing debt, and the subsequent need for a deleveraging of business and household balance sheets. The period was challenging for policy as well. The Federal Reserve (Fed) initially turned to reductions in the Federal Funds rate in an effort to stimulate the economy through the transmission of these lower rates to other short-term market rates. Despite the Federal Funds rate in the range of 0.0 to 0.25 percent, the economy failed to pick up significantly. The Fed turned to what has been described as an unconventional monetary policy, quantitative easing, whereby it purchased bonds, mainly U.S. Treasury and housing agency securities, to help smooth the operation of credit markets. This recovery was notable for the lack of stimulus through fiscal policy. Stimulus packages were passed during the downturn in 2008 and 2009, but fiscal stimulus was far less expansionary in the recent recovery compared to historical averages.

By the end of 2015, the Fed began to increase the Federal Funds rate and by 2017 the economy was showing a number of signs of strength. But the deep recession and slow recovery had been experienced to different degrees across industries.

Industrial Performance

Below we show the recent output growth rates in the recovery (2009 – 2016) in a group of 19 industries that together make up the economy. The industry definitions and the corresponding production data are both based on the NAICS (North American Industry Classification System). The list of industries and the growth in their output over the past three years are shown in the figure below.


Data Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and ESG Calculations

The top performers include the Information industry, which consists of both traditional publishing firms and electronic publishing outlets as well as firms in the relatively newer areas of data hosting and web service portals, the business-oriented Professional, Scientific and Technical service industry and the more consumer service-oriented Arts and Entertainment industry. Modestly above-average growth is seen in the Healthcare and Social Assistance, Retail Trade (which includes traditional department stores as well as electronic shopping) and the Accommodation and Food Service industries. Weaker growth is seen in the Manufacturing, Educational service and Finance and Insurance industries, and Government.

How does the recovery in these industries compare with past recoveries? To answer this question we select several industries. The figures below use the same technique used in the graph of GDP to examine the relationship of the performance of these industries in the current recovery to past recoveries.

Data Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and ESG Calculations

The figures show that while the recovery of output in the Professional, Scientific and Technical Services, Accommodation and Food Service and Retail industries was quite strong and roughly on par with the 2000s recovery, in all cases output growth was considerably weaker than in the combined recoveries in the 1980s and 1990s. After a slow start, the growth of output in the Healthcare and Social Assistance industry has matched its growth in the 1980s and 1990s but it is still less robust than its recovery during the 2000s. Both the Manufacturing and Finance and Insurance industries are experiencing the weakest recovery of any of the past cycles.

Going forward, interest rates are projected to rise and the monetary accommodation through quantitative easing to be reduced. How vulnerable these industries are to a monetary tightening will depend on their exposure to a variety of factors:

  • The level of corporate debt: Higher interest rates carry risks for industries as they raise the cost of new borrowing as well as the cost of existing debt service thus leading to pressures to curtail operations and put off investments.
  • Consumer spending. Higher rates can affect consumer spending as the availability and terms of consumer finance are key factors, particularly for relatively big-ticket items such as automobiles and other durable goods.
  • Housing demand. Mortgage interest payments and availability of credit are a key influence on housing affordability.
  • International trade and exchange rates. In theory, higher interest rates on U.S. assets increase the demand for dollars and lead to a dollar appreciation. As a result, exports become more expensive in dollar terms abroad and, correspondingly, imports become less expensive to U.S. residents. These effects can be particularly important for U.S. manufacturers of consumer and capital goods that face stiff competition in foreign markets, as well as industries related to travel and tourism.

Thus, we anticipate that sectors such as construction and manufacturing that require big projects consisting of purchases of equipment, machinery, and land will be vulnerable to interest rate hikes for two reasons. First, the cost of undertaking such projects will be higher. Second, the demand for their products depends on consumers’ borrowing that will be impacted by high rates. Manufacturing also has a large export component that is likely to be hurt by potential loss of competitiveness. Sectors such as retail and services sectors are unlikely to be severely affected by interest rate changes since these sectors neither invest in costly long-term projects nor have a demand that require consumer borrowing.

Why Does It Still Not Feel Like Recovery? A Look at Industry Performance2018-07-04T19:37:48+00:00

Greek Debt in Historical Perspective: An Opinion Article

Anthony Rodolakis
November 22, 2017

Current fiscal proposals are projected to lead to a sizeable increase in U.S. debt and while people point to the Greek crisis to warn about high debt, a closer look at Greece’s debt history reveals few similarities. Modern Greek economic history is a history of debt. Greece is the country with more years in default to its creditors than any other European nation, being in default in 48 percent of the years since 1826.

[1] As of 2016, Greek debt stood at roughly 181 percent of GDP and more than twice the average of the Euro area (19 countries). In this post, we present a brief narrative of some selected major episodes of the buildup of debt in Greece to highlight the different sources of Greece’s debt problems over its recent history.

The 19th Century

By the late 1700s Greece’s proximity to Europe and a flourishing trade had allowed the development of a rich merchant class which was able to benefit from the European intellectual enlightenment – and to a large extent precipitate the ground for political independence from the Ottoman Turks. The vast majority of the peasantry, however, had been left in a semi-feudal status and beholden to the local oligarchies for favors.

Greece gained independence in 1830, following a turbulent revolutionary war. The debt buildup of that period was largely for loans to finance the war expenditures. The debt burdens the country had accumulated during the war lingered through the 1830s and 1840s and eventually led to a default in 1843. Fifty years were to elapse before the default was terminated.[2]

Following the final settlement of the default in 1878, Greece tapped the French capital markets for close to 500,000,000 francs. The terms, however, contained substantial “haircuts,” which was often the case. For example, an 1884 loan of 170,000,000 francs was offered at 68.5 percent, though even then it was undersubscribed with net proceeds of only 100,000,000 francs.[3] In all cases, bondholders were pledged a variety of receipts such as from the state monopolies of petroleum, matches, playing cards, tobacco consumption taxes, and port custom receipts. Nevertheless, both British and French financial experts sent to Greece around this time to examine the stability of finances and the ability to repay the contracted loans on behalf of their banking institutions concluded that bankruptcy was inevitable.[4]

The inability to maintain external debt obligations together with the expenses for the program of internal infrastructure development as well as renewed military expenditures led to the 1893 suspension of payments.

The 20th Century

During the first decade of the 20th century, Greece pursued a strict policy of monetary restraint and fiscal discipline that led to an appreciating drachma. Greece enjoyed rapid growth in certain sectors with the shipping industry exploiting the expanding trade opportunities. The fiscal and monetary self-discipline of those years paid off with net positive capital inflows from abroad. By 1920, the end of the Balkan wars and World War I saw a doubling of the territorial size and population of Greece.

Fast forwarding, the end of World War II found Greece and Europe in ruins, but Greece endured another round of fighting. Through 1949 Greece fought a bloody civil war between communists and the National Army that devastated the country, with widespread infrastructure destruction and rapid migration abroad. The Civil War retarded political and economic advances in Greece for several decades, handicapping the country’s economic growth compared to other European nations.

The 1950s and 1960s saw rapid rates of growth in the Greek economy premised on large public investments on infrastructure, foreign direct investment, residential investment and a strengthening commercial shipping sector. Despite this growth, “the development during this period is dependent on foreign funding and is asymmetric and unproductive.”[5] In 1950 a Daily Herald correspondent concluded that there are two Greek kingdoms: that of the new-rich of the center of Athens and the aristocratic suburbs and that of the rest of Greece where malnutrition and tuberculosis reigned.

With the entry into the European Economic Community in 1981, Greece was able to participate in a community of advanced and wealthy nations. However, the availability of development funds was to prove a double-edged sword. “According to OECD data, between 1981 and 1988, the number of central government public sector employees increased six times more than the active population of the country during the same time period, and public expenditures as a percent of the domestic product skyrocketed from 21 percent in 1976 to 51 percent in 1988.”[6] Overall, between “1975 and 1987, in 13 years, $18.4 billion in loans were contracted, of which $14.8 billion, or 80.6 percent, were allocated for the servicing of existing debt”[7] and not for development. At the end of the decade, the debt/GDP ratio stood at 66 percent.

The 1990s saw Greece struggling to implement the conditions required by the European Union (EU) convergence criteria on its path to full monetary union within the Eurozone. Successive Greek governments attempted to contain inflation and largely succeeded, but inflows from EU funds continued alongside the inability to balance the budget. The conservative government of the early 1990s increased debt by 295 percent, which pushed total debt as a share of GDP above 100 percent. Total debt servicing consumed 151.2 percent of regular government receipts as of the end of 1993.[8]

With the entry of Greece into the Eurozone in 2001 a new era of optimism and GDP growth had begun, unfortunately, premised on loans at deceptively low-interest rates. In the 2000s Greece was exposed to an international financial environment flooded with liquidity and without any real convergence with the “core” of the EU, continued lack of fiscal discipline, and with already high levels of debt. Greece was allowed to accumulate a debt of over 300 billion Euros that was to allocate the funds to its preferred oligarchic economic cartels that controlled construction projects and other outlets for the contracted loans, as well as allow largesse to the ever-expanding public sector.

The 2000s, much like the 1980s and the 1990s, proved a lost decade. The long-promised and much-needed deregulation of cartels across industrial sectors, labor market liberalization, privatization of publicly controlled enterprises, improvement of public administration, restructuring of public and private pension systems, and efficient absorption of EU funds for infrastructure upgrades were delayed or outright ignored by stakeholders. Political leaders avoided any and all direct conflict with their constituencies that tended to be concentrated in the public and private sector unions.

In Sum

The staggering Greek debt accumulated over the last 20 years is not a unique phenomenon for present-day Greece. Since the 1820s historical, political, demographic, and sociological circumstances have led to multiple periods of borrowing, default, and setbacks to growth as the nation struggled to repay its debts. The record-setting level of the current debt makes Greece extremely fragile and vulnerable to unforeseen circumstances.

[1]This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly”, Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, Princeton University Press, 2011.

[2]State Insolvency and Foreign Bondholders: Selected Case Histories of Governmental Foreign Bond Defaults and Debt Readjustments”, William H. Wynne, 1951, p. 298.

[3] Ibid. p. 298.

[4] Ibid p. 304

[5] Ibid. p. 271.

[6]Foreign Loans at the birth and development of the New Greek State 1824-2009,” T. M. Hliadakis, 2011, Mpatsioulas Publishers, p. 364.

[7] Ibid. Page 393.

[8] Ibid. Page 419.

The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect any policy or position of the New York State Assembly.
Greek Debt in Historical Perspective: An Opinion Article2018-07-04T19:37:48+00:00
Go to Top