April 24: New York State Department of Labor Reported That Employment Statewide Was Flat in March

The New York State Department of Labor reported a gain of only 500 jobs statewide in March, following a gain of almost 30,000 in February.  Employment in the state is up 1.1% over a year-ago compared to 1.5% for the nation. The Bureau of Labor Statistics reported that New York City lost 2,600 jobs in March following a gain of about 22,000 in February.  Employment in the city is up 1.8% over a year ago. Read more

April 24: New York State Department of Labor Reported That Employment Statewide Was Flat in March2018-04-25T03:02:19+00:00

U.S. Tax Reform: Where Are We Now?

Rubaiyat Tasnim and the ESG
April 12, 2018

On February 28, 2018, the Graduate Center Public Programs and the Stone Center on Socio-Economic Inequality held a panel on tax reform where experts discussed its implications and how it will impact different constituencies. Panelists were: Larry Kotlikoff, the William Fairfield Warren Professor and Economics Professor at Boston University; Lily Batchelder, the Frederick and Grace Stokes Professor of Law at NYU School of Law and Professor at the NYU’s Wagner School; Leonard Burman, co-founder of the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, the Paul Volcker Professor and Professor of Public Administration and International Affairs at the Maxwell School, and a Senior Research Associate at the Syracuse University; and the Nobel Laureate Paul Krugman, a Distinguished Professor of Economics at the Graduate Center and New York Times columnist. The discussion was moderated by Kathleen Hays, global economics and policy editor at Bloomberg.

Statements by Panelists on the Tax Bill

Paul Krugman started off the discussion by questioning why we are cutting taxes at this point in the business cycle. The US economy is at full employment and the government is in deficit. As the US population is growing older, the burden of maintaining programs such as Medicaid, Medicare, and Social Security is growing as well. The tax cut is only worsening our fiscal condition.

Leonard Burman stated that the tax system needs to be reformed and pointed out the problems of the current system including its inefficiency, complexity, unfairness, and inability to raise enough revenue for the government. The Congressional Budget Office has projected 10 trillion dollars in deficits over the next decade. The US corporate tax rate is high compared to other nations, but the tax bill cut the tax rate for unincorporated business as well which is not very high relative to other countries. The bill succeeded in giving the Republican Party a legislative victory which not only helped them undermine the Affordable Care Act but might also behave the way Reagan’s 1981 tax cut did – it may distort the tax code much more to generate momentum for another tax reform in five years.

Lily Batchelder started her introduction by stating that she has been a fan of tax reform but it is setting out to do the exact opposite of what she was expecting. The tax reform should have addressed the long-term fiscal issues through generating more revenue. The bill is very heavily tilted towards tax cuts for the wealthy. As it is increasing the deficit, it is putting social programs in danger in the future. She highlighted the biggest new loophole in the code: The new pass through deduction cuts taxes for unincorporated businesses and greatly complicates the administration of the tax code to try to ensure that individuals do not form an unincorporated business to avoid the higher individual tax rate.

Laurence Kotlikoff agreed with other panelists about the current condition of US economy, and noted that enormous amounts of off the book debt and contingent liabilities, which when properly accounted for, makes it a 200 trillion dollar debt rather than a 20 trillion dollar debt. He believes the tax reform has positive elements and that there will be a significant increase in capital formation in the country, a 15% increase over time and a 5 and half percent increase in wages, which would offset the increase in debt to GDP ratio. The unfunded liabilities grow by about 6 trillion dollars per year, which compared to the increase in debt of about 1.6 trillion dollars in 10 years is much more substantial. He argued that the tax reform did not increase inequality. As the share of spending of the top 1% within each group will not change at all, he states that the tax reform is fair. The absolute amount of tax benefits for richer will be higher as they pay higher taxes.

Supply side: Will the companies invest more and create more jobs?

L. Kotlikoff argued that as the marginal corporate tax is lowered from 34.6% to 18.8%, a lot of capital from abroad will come in and will be staying in the US. This will impact wages by increasing them by 5.5% over the next ten years. The consumption rate is extremely high, with national saving rate at only 4%, and with a domestic investment rate of 5%, only 1% of national income is being invested from abroad into US. As the country saves too little, the reform will help move capital from abroad.

P. Krugman agreed with L. Kotlikoff that it will attract capital from abroad, but believes it will take a long time. If the bill works, it will still nonetheless produce huge trade deficits for a decade or more. This trade deficit will lead to strong dollars which will deter investments. The corporate profits in US are a return to monopoly power. As taxes are cut on monopolies and new investments are not generated, this will increase wages. As more capital moves from all over the world to the US, it will raise the return on capital all over the world. With more capital from abroad being invested, the returns paid to them will increase and the net benefit to the residents will be only the tax wedge. Foreigners already own a third of equity in US and this tax reform cuts taxes on that. Keeping all these factors in mind, this tax reform will fail to increase income and it will only exacerbate the deficit problem.

L. Batchelder pointed out how there could have been a way to do business tax reform that could help the economy in the long run. This bill loses a huge amount of revenue and may not have been a good time to act on an economic stimulus. The positive growth effects of the tax reform disappear and potentially reverse. Raising taxes in the future or cutting spending programs may be necessary to pay for the tax reform and will likely put a drag on growth.

L. Burman added to these points by stating how the models developed by the Joint Committee on Taxation do not produce the big macro effects advocated by the supporters of the tax reform. The bill allows firms to immediately deduct the cost of new investments, called expensing. Theoretically, this will encourage them to invest more, make workers more productive and could raise wages. Empirically, there has not been a huge response to tax reforms in many countries or even within the United States. The tax rate cut to foreign holders of US equities will only benefit the foreign equity holders. He gave the example of 1986 corporate tax rate cut which led to other US trading partners to cut their tax rates in response, eventually reducing the effectiveness of tax rate cuts.

What Is the Tax Reform’s Impact on the Economy and Will It Benefit All?

P. Krugman stated that the tax reform will lead to more spending. But it would have been better to have done that when the unemployment rate was 9.5% rather than now. The fast economic growth will also see a hike in interest rates by Jay Powell, the new chairman of the Federal Reserve, which will limit the effect of the tax reform. So, the increase in consumer confidence will not initiate much growth. The deficit spending in a full employment economy will react differently than deficit spending in a depressed economy. Orders for new capital equipment, which is the first early indicator of an investment surge has not gone up yet.

L. Burman, addressing the stock market rise, stressed the point that the increase in profitability is from the companies making decisions assuming a tax rate of 35%. The value of the profitable companies go up when the income is taxed at 21%, which is a one-time shift and unlikely to continue. The observation that a lot of the companies are paying bonuses and wages are going up are not anomalies at this stage of economic cycle. As the labor market is getting tighter, the companies are competing to keep their workers through bonuses.

L. Batchelder distinguished between the direct and indirect effects of tax bill. She terms this bill as an “incredibly regressive bill” when considering the direct effects on employee compensation or wages. As an example, the average tax cut for a household with $40-50,000 is about $400, while a household with a million dollars’ income gets a tax cut of $27,000. Adding on the indirect effects, as calculated by JCT, 25% of all corporate tax cuts benefits labor. Incorporating all these effects, the tax cuts for the wealthy is three times larger than they are for the middle class. As the individual provisions expire, every income group earning less than $75,000 on average loses out.

L. Kotlikoff disagreed arguing that the tax reform is not regressive. He explained that the same tax rate cut for rich means a bigger absolute tax break, as they earn more to begin with. Looking at the inequality in spending, the share of spending in the top 1% in any age-cohort remain unchanged and so does the share of taxes they pay. He terms the tax reform as a “second-rate reform,” because it failed to raise revenue and will undermine public education and Obama Care, leading to another 10 million people being uninsured. He emphasizes comparing people within their age group when comparing taxes paid.

P. Krugman focused on the lost revenue that has to be offset by spending less on social programs. So, the effects on the after-tax-and-transfer distribution of income makes the tax reform regressive, impoverishing the government even further.

L. Kotlikoff stated that despite some simplifications in the tax code, the pass-through still remains complicated.

Batchelder stated that the pass through deduction opens up huge gaming opportunities. She added that the pass-through deduction is providing the largest benefits to the wealthy, with the top 1% earning 50% of the pass-through business income. A pass-through business refers to certain ways to organize a business in which profits are immediately passed through to owners and are subject to the individual-level tax but not a corporate –level tax. These business forms include sole proprietorships, partnerships, and S-corporations. The pass-though deduction allows these businesses to write off 20% of business income to try to make up for the higher individual tax rate that pass-throughs are subject to but also limits the deduction. The limitations are complex and this creates more complication than simplification.

U.S. Tax Reform: Where Are We Now?2018-07-04T19:37:46+00:00

New York City Job Growth: Healthy, but Divergent Across Sectors

James Orr
March 27, 2018

Recently-released employment data show job growth in New York City in 2017 was down only mildly from its pace in 2016 and is still above the comparable nationwide rate. On an average annual basis, employment in New York City expanded 2.0 percent in 2017 following a gain of 2.1 percent in 2016; these city growth rates, however, fall short of the 3.0 percent job growth rate in the city in 2015. For the state as a whole, job growth rates in each of the past two years were below those of the city and also slightly below the national rate, a pattern that has held for much of the roughly eight year period since the recovery of employment in New York got underway. This post examines these state and city employment trends and highlights the recent job performance in key sectors making up the New York City economy.

Employment Trends in New York City and New York State

The recovery of employment in New York City from the downturn and financial crisis began in late 2009 and has been quite strong compared to the nation. The figure below, also presented here, shows the robust recovery of employment in the city relative to both the nation and the state in this recovery. Job growth in the city had shown some weakness in late summer 2017, as discussed in an earlier post, but subsequent gains helped the city achieve healthy growth, 2.0 percent, for the year as a whole. In terms of job counts, the city added about 85,000 jobs in 2017 compared to just under 90,000 in 2016. The figure also indicates a declining rate of job growth in the past two years relative to the strong gains seen in 2014 and 2015 which roughly matched or exceeded 3.0 percent. In 2015, for instance, the city added 123,000 jobs. A measure of economic activity in the city also shows a pattern of strong though gradually slowing growth over the past several years.

Statewide, the recovery of employment has generally not been as strong as in the city. In 2017 job growth in the state was 1.3 percent, slightly below its 2016 pace and below both the city’s growth and the 1.6 percent job growth in the nation. As has been discussed previously, this disparity in growth across areas in New York State has persisted for some time and reflects the relatively slower pace of employment growth in the metropolitan areas in upstate and western New York. The more rapid job growth in downstate areas was again seen in 2017, though it should be noted that growth continued at a relatively strong pace in the Albany area and, after slipping for much of 2016, growth picked up in the Buffalo area.

Performance of Key Sectors in New York City

The relatively healthy overall job growth in New York City in 2017 reflects the net effects of growth in the diverse sectors that make up the city’s economy. The figure below shows the annual average job growth rates in 2016 and 2017 in the sectors making major positive contributions to growth.

Among the sectors, annual average job growth in 2017 was strongest in three of the city’s largest services sectors—education and health, professional and business services, and leisure and hospitality. Nationwide, these sectors also were high performers in 2017, with annual growth rates for each at 2.0 percent or more. The education and health sector in the city increased its growth rate over 2016 led by continued strong expansion of jobs in the health component. Growth rates in both the professional and business services and leisure and hospitality sectors in the city, however, were slightly off their 2016 rates.

Job growth was also high in the construction sector which reflects, in part, the continued high growth of residential building permits in the city. While strong, growth in the sector was off its 5.6 percent pace in 2016.

The information and transportation and warehousing sectors made relatively strong contributions to job growth in 2017 and both sectors expanded moderately faster than in 2016. Developments in the transportation and warehousing sector has been linked to the evolution of shopping trends, specifically, the decline in employment in traditional department stores and the corresponding rise of online shopping. The increasing demand for storage and delivery of items bought online likely is related to the changing nature of consumer shopping, a nationwide trend that is playing out in New York City.

Employment in the city’s financial activities sector, which includes the securities sector (Wall Street), banks, insurance companies and real estate firms, expanded by 0.8 percent in 2017, down from its gain of 1.4 percent in 2016. Jobs in the securities component were essentially flat in 2017 after rising by about 4,000 in 2016. Jobs here account for a little less than 5.0 percent of city private sector jobs but it has an outsized role in the city’s economy as the sector accounts for a little over 20 percent of private sector earnings. These high earnings gives the sector an important role in supporting demand and in city and state tax revenues.

The figure below shows annual average job growth rates in 2016 and 2017 in the sectors with weaker or negative contributions to job growth.

The retail trade sector in the city had modest job gains in 2017 following losses in 2016 and, as noted above, growth in the sector has been constrained to some extent in recent years by the shift of consumers to online shopping. In fact, the level of overall retail employment in the city has been fluctuating around 350,000 each year since 2014. Job growth in the government sector was flat in 2017 following a slight gain in 2016, mirroring national trends. Local government employment is the largest component of the sector in the city and current employment totals there remain roughly at the level they reached just prior to the downturn in the city’s economy.

Wholesale trade employment in the city saw modest declines in 2017 following an essentially flat performance in 2016. Jobs in the wholesale trade sector, as with retail trade, have been not expanding in line with the city’s generally robust job performance and the level of employment has been fluctuating around 145,000 since 2014.

The city’s manufacturing sector had a significant decline in jobs in 2017, losing 3.9 percent of employment, following a decline of 2.2 percent in 2016. As in the nation, this sector in the city has been experiencing secular declines in employment and job counts are down by about 20,000, or roughly 26.0 percent, over the past ten years.

Looking Ahead

The recent employment picture in the New York City economy is one of fairly healthy growth though the pace has slowed from the relatively high rates of previous years. Two reports project that this gradual slowing in the rate of overall city job growth will continue over the next several years. It is likely that the three major services sectors in the city that have been key drivers of job growth–education and health, professional and business services and leisure and hospitality—will continue to be sources of new jobs going forward. Some offset to these gains could come from further declines in the city’s retail trade and manufacturing sectors.

One factor that can be expected to influence the city’s job growth is the performance of the national economy. Projections have economic growth picking up a bit in 2018 over its 2017 pace but then slowing modestly through 2020. A risk to the outlook is that the national economy expands less than expected and thus weighs down city employment growth. Another risk arises from the provision in the recently-passed Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 which limits the size of the individual federal deduction for state and local tax payments. It remains to be seen what the consequences of this legislation will be for the state and city economies.

New York City Job Growth: Healthy, but Divergent Across Sectors2018-07-04T19:37:46+00:00

March 21: Federal Reserve to Raise Fed Funds Target Range to 1.50 to 1.75 Percent

In view of realized and expected labor market conditions and inflation, the Federal Reserve FMOC decided to raise the target range for the federal funds rate to 1-1/2 to 1-3/4 percent. The stance of monetary policy remains accommodative, thereby supporting strong labor market conditions and a sustained return to 2 percent inflation. Read more

March 21: Federal Reserve to Raise Fed Funds Target Range to 1.50 to 1.75 Percent2018-03-21T20:52:23+00:00

March 09: Total Non-Farm Payroll Employment Increased by 313,000 in February

Total non-farm payroll employment increased by 313,000 in February, and the unemployment rate was unchanged at 4.1 percent, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today. Employment rose in construction, retail trade, professional and business services, manufacturing, financial activities, and mining. Read more

March 09: Total Non-Farm Payroll Employment Increased by 313,000 in February2018-03-12T00:16:56+00:00

The Welfare State in the Age of Globalization

Branko Milanovic
March 05, 2018

It has become a truism to say that the welfare state is under stress from the effects of globalization and migration and thus may not be able to provide the same level of income support that it had provided in the past. In my previous post that looked at policies to reduce inequality in the 21st century, I mentioned that I would follow up with a discussion of the welfare state. In this post I want to go back to the origins of the welfare state to understand the origin of the current stress.

As Avner Offer has recently reminded us in his excellent book (co-authored with Daniel Söderberg), the origin of social democracy and the welfare state is in the realization (and financial ability to deal with it) that all people in their lives go through periods where they are not earning anything, but have to consume: this applies to the young (hence children’s benefits), to the sick (health care and sick pay), to those who had a misfortune to get injured at work (worker’s accident insurance), to mothers when they give birth (parental leave), to people who lose jobs (unemployment benefits), and to the elderly (pensions). The welfare state was created to provide these benefits, delivered in the form of insurance, for either unavoidable or very common conditions. It was built on the assumed commonality of behavior or, differently put, cultural and often ethnic homogeneity. It is no accident that the prototypical welfare state born in Sweden in the 1930s, had many elements of (not used here in a pejorative sense) national socialism.

In addition to commonality of behavior and experiences, the welfare state, in order to be sustainable, required mass participation. Social insurance cannot work on small parts of the workforce because it then naturally leads to adverse selection, a point well illustrated by the endless wrangles over US health care. The rich, or those who are unlikely to be unemployed, or the healthy ones, do not want to subsidize the “others” and opt out. The system that would rely only on the “others” is unsustainable because of huge premiums it would require. Thus the welfare state can work only when it covers all, or almost all, of the labor force, i.e. when it is (1) massive and (2) includes people with similar conditions.

Globalization erodes both requirements. Trade globalization has led to the well-documented decline in the share of the middle class in most western countries and the polarization of income. With income polarization the rich realize that they are better off creating their own private systems because sharing the systems with those who are substantially poorer implies sizeable income transfers. This leads to “social separatism” of the rich, reflected in the growing importance of private health plans, private pensions, and private education. The bottom line is that a very unequal, or polarized, society cannot maintain an extensive welfare state.

Economic migration, to which most of the rich societies have been newly exposed in the past fifty years (especially so in Europe), also undercuts the support for the welfare state. This happens through the inclusion of people with actual or perceived differences in social norms or lifecycle experiences. It is the same phenomenon as dubbed by Peter Lindert as a lack of “affinity” between the white majority and African Americans in the US which rendered the US welfare state historically smaller than its European counterparts. The same process is now taking place in Europe where large pockets of immigrants have not been assimilated and where the native population believes that the migrants are getting an unfair share of the benefits. Lack of affinity need not be construed as some sinister discrimination. Sometimes it could be indeed that, but more often it may be grounded in correct thinking that one is unlikely to experience the lifecycle events of the same nature or frequency as the others, and is hence unwilling to contribute to such an insurance. In the US, the underlying fact that African Americans are more likely to be unemployed probably led to less generous unemployment benefits; similarly, the underlying fact that migrants are likely to have more children than the natives might lead to the curtailment of children’s benefits. In any case, the difference in expected lifetime experiences undermines the homogeneity necessary for a sustainable welfare state.

In addition, in the era of globalization more developed welfare states might experience a perverse effect of attracting less skilled or less ambitious migrants. Under “everything being the same” conditions, a decision of a migrant where to emigrate will depend on the expected income in one country vs. another. In principle, that would favor richer countries. But we have also to include a migrant’s expectation regarding where in the income distribution of the recipient country she expects to end up. If she expects to be in the low income deciles, then a more egalitarian country with a larger welfare state will be more attractive. An opposite calculation will be made by the migrants who expect to end up in the higher deciles of the recipient countries’ income distributions. If the former migrants are either less skilled or less ambitious than the latter, then the less skilled will tend to choose countries with more developed welfare states. Hence the adverse selection.

In very abstract terms, the countries that would be exposed to the sharpest adverse selection will be those with large welfare states and low income mobility. Migrants going to such countries cannot expect, even in the next generation, to have children who would climb up the income ladder. In a destructive feedback, such countries will attract the least skilled or the least ambitious migrants and, once they create an underclass, the upward mobility of their children will be limited. The system then works like a self-fulfilling prophecy: it attracts ever more unskilled migrants who fail to assimilate. The natives tend to see migrants as generally lacking in skills and ambition (which may be true because these are the kinds of people their country attracts) and hence as “different”. At the same time, failure to be accepted will be seen by the migrants as confirmation of natives’ anti-migrant prejudices, or, even worse, as religious or ethnic discrimination.

There is no easy solution to the vicious circle faced by developed welfare states in the era of globalization. This is why I argued in my previous blog for (1) policies that would lead toward equalization of endowments so that eventually taxation of current income can be reduced and the size of the welfare state be brought down, and (2) that the nature of migration be changed so that it be much more akin to temporary labor without automatic access to citizenship and the entire gamut of welfare benefits. This last point is discussed in Chapter 3 of my “Global inequality” as well as here.

The original post can be found at GlobalInequality.

The Welfare State in the Age of Globalization2018-07-04T19:37:46+00:00

Why 20th Century Tools Cannot Be Used to Address 21st Century Income Inequality

Branko Milanovic
February 16, 2018

The remarkable period of reduced income and wealth inequality in the rich countries, roughly from the end of the Second World War to the early 1980s, relied on four pillars: strong trade unions, mass education, high taxes and large government transfers. Since the increase of inequality twenty or more years ago, the failed attempts to stem its further rise have relied on trying, or at least advocating, the expansion of all or some of the four pillars. But neither of them will do the job in the 21st century.

Why? Consider trade unions first. The decline of trade union density, present in all rich countries and especially strong in the private sector, is not the product of more inimical government policies only. They might have contributed to the decline but are not the main cause of it. The underlying organization of labor changed. The shift from manufacturing to services and from enforced presence on factory floors or offices to remote work implied a multiplication of relatively small work units, often not located physically in the same place. Organizing a dispersed workforce is much more difficult than organizing workers who work in a single huge plant and share a single interest. In addition, the declining role of the unions is a reflection of the diminished power of labor vis-à-vis capital, due to the massive expansion of wage labor (that is, labor working under a capitalist system) since the end of the Cold War, and China’s re-integration into the world economy. While the latter was a one-off shock, its effects will persist for at least several decades, and may be reinforced by future high population growth rates in Africa, thus keeping the relative abundance of labor undiminished.

Mass education was a tool for reducing inequality in the West in the period when the average number of years of schooling increased from 4 or 6 in the 1950s to 13 or more today. This led to a reduction in the skill premium, the gap between college educated and those with only high or elementary school, so much so that the famous Dutch economist Jan Tinbergen believed in the mid-1970s that by the turn of the century the skill premium will be zero. But mass expansion of education is impossible when a country has reached 13 or 14 years of education on average simply because the maximum level of education is bounded from above. Thus, we cannot expect small increases in the average education levels to provide the equalizing effect on wages that mass education once did.

High taxation of current income and high social transfers were crucial to reduce income inequality. But their further increases are politically difficult. The main reason may be a much more skeptical view of the role of government and of tax-and-transfer policies that is now shared by the middle classes in many countries compared to their predecessors half a century ago. This is not saying that people just want lower taxation or are unaware that without high taxes the systems of social security, free education, modern infrastructure etc. would collapse. But it is saying that the electorate is more skeptical about the gains to be achieved from additional increases in taxes imposed on current income and that such increases are unlikely to find support.

So if the high underlying inequality is a threat to social homogeneity and democracy, what tools should be used to fight it? It is where I think we need to think not only out of the box in purely instrumental fashion, but to set ourselves a new objective: an egalitarian capitalism based on approximately equal endowments of both capital and skills across the population. Such capitalism generates egalitarian outcomes even without a large redistributionist state. To put it in simple terms: If the rich have only twice as many units of capital and twice as many units of skill than the poor, and if the returns per unit of capital and skill are approximately equal, then overall inequality cannot be more than 2 to 1.

How can endowments be equalized? As far as capital is concerned, by a deconcentration of ownership of assets. As far as labor is concerned, mostly through equalization of returns to the approximately same skill levels. In one case, it passes through equalization of the stock of endowments, in the other through equalization of the returns to the stocks (of education).

Let us start with capital. It is a remarkable fact that the concentration of wealth and income from property has remained at the incredibly high level of about 90 Gini points or more since the 1970s in all rich countries. This is to a large extent the key reason why the change in the relative power of capital over labor and the increase in the capital share in net output was directly translated into a higher inter-personal inequality. This obvious fact was overlooked simply because it is so…obvious. We are used to thinking that as the capital share goes up, so must income inequality. Yes, this is true—but it is true because capital is extremely concentrated and thus an increase in a very unequal source of income must push overall inequality up.

But if capital ownership becomes less concentrated then an increase in the share of capital that may be (let’s suppose) inevitable because of international forces, such as China’s move to capitalism, does not need to lead to higher inequality within individual rich countries.

The methods to reduce capital concentration are not new or unknown. They were just never used seriously and consistently. We can divide them into three groups. First, favorable tax policies (including a guaranteed minimum rate of return) to make equity ownership more attractive to small and medium shareholders (and less attractive to big shareholders, that is, a policy exactly the opposite of what exists today in the United States). Second, increased worker ownership through Employee Stock Ownership Plans or other company-level incentives. Third, use of an inheritance or wealth tax as a means to even out access to capital by using tax proceeds to give every young adult a capital grant (as recently proposed by Tony Atkinson).

What to do with labor? There, in a rich and well-educated society, the issue is not just to make education more accessible to those who did not have a chance to study (although that too is obviously important) but to equalize the returns to education between equally educated people. A significant source of wage inequality is not any longer the difference in years of schooling, but the difference in wages (for the same number of years of education) based either on the perceived or actual difference in school qualities. The way to reduce this inequality is to equalize the quality of schools. This, in the US, and increasingly in Europe as well, implies an improvement in the quality of public schools. This can be achieved only by large investments in improved public education and by withdrawals of numerous advantages (including tax-free status) enjoyed by private universities that command huge financial endowments. Without the leveling of the playing field between private and public schools, a mere increase in the number of years of schooling or the ability of a rare child of lower middle class status to attend elite colleges (that increasingly serve only the rich), will not reduce inequality in labor incomes.

The original post can be found at GlobalInequality.

Why 20th Century Tools Cannot Be Used to Address 21st Century Income Inequality2018-07-04T19:37:46+00:00

Consumption Taxes, Income Taxes, and Revenue Sensitivity: States and the Great Recession

Published in Public Finance Review, 2017
Howard Chernick, Hunter College and Graduate Center, CUNY; and Cordelia Reimers, Hunter College and Graduate Center, CUNY

The major sources of state tax revenue are personal income taxes and taxes on consumption – general sales and gross receipts taxes and excise taxes on tobacco, alcohol, and gasoline. Which source of tax revenue was more stable during the Great Recession? Contrary to conventional wisdom, we find that personal income taxes were a more stable source of revenue than consumption taxes during the Great Recession.

The conventional wisdom says that consumption taxes are more stable than taxes on income because the consumption tax base is less elastic than the income tax base with respect to changes in aggregate income (Tax Foundation 2013). We question the conventional wisdom that heavier state reliance on income taxation as opposed to consumption taxes increases the sensitivity of tax revenues to the business cycle. Our results show that for high income tax states, shifting to a more consumption-based tax structure would impose considerable reductions in tax progressivity, but would not have reduced the cyclical sensitivity of tax revenues during the Great Recession. If states with high income tax shares were to lower their reliance on the income tax, the revenue decline during the recession would have been greater; while states with high consumption-tax shares would have had smaller declines in tax revenue if they had higher income tax shares.

Using the Great Recession as a test case, we show that even controlling for policy responses, the shares of state taxes from the personal income tax and sales and excise taxes at the outset of the recession are unable to explain the variation in the change in tax revenue across states. By contrast, we find that an income distributional approach, in which the shock to different income classes is interacted with differences in effective tax burdens by income class, is able to explain a substantial portion of the variability of tax revenue changes during the Great Recession.

The interactions between tax burdens and recession-related shocks to the tax base by income class are key to our finding that states that rely heavily on income taxation were not more cyclically unstable than high consumption tax states. A second factor is that, among those states with highly unequal income distributions and heavy reliance on income taxation, there was a greater willingness to offset the recession shock by imposing income tax surcharges.

We emphasize that our study is based on a single, albeit important, episode – the change in state tax revenues from 2007 to 2009 induced by the Great Recession. We do not claim to have proved that the conventional wisdom – that consumption taxes are more stable than income taxes – is always incorrect. To be able to do so, our approach would have to be applied to a longer time period than just two years, in order to incorporate multiple downturns and recoveries.

Paper

Consumption Taxes, Income Taxes, and Revenue Sensitivity: States and the Great Recession2018-07-04T19:37:47+00:00
Go to Top